POLLOCK v. FARMERS' LOAN
AND TRUST COMPANY.
No. 893.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
157 U.S. 429; 15 S. Ct. 673; 1895 U.S. LEXIS 2215; 39 L. Ed. 759;
3 A.F.T.R. (P-H) 2557
Argued March 7, 8, 11, 12, 13, 1895.
April 8, 1895, Decided
PRIOR HISTORY: [***1]
APPEAL FROM THE CIRCUIT COURT OF THE UNITED STATES FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF
NEW YORK.
THIS was a bill filed by Charles Pollock, a citizen of the State of Massachusetts,
on behalf of himself and all other stockholders of the defendant company
similarly situated, against the Farmers' Loan and Trust Company, a corporation
of the State of New York, and its directors, alleging that the capital stock of
the corporation consisted of one million dollars, divided into forty thousand
shares of the par value of twenty-five dollars each; that the company was
authorized to invest its assets in public stocks and bonds of the United
States, of individual States, or of any incorporated city, or county, or in
such real or personal securities as it might deem proper; and also to take,
accept, and execute all such trusts of every description as might be committed
to it by any person or persons or any corporation, by grant, assignment,
devise, or bequest, or by order of any court of record of New York, and to
receive and take any real estate which might be the subject of such trust; that
the property and assets of the company amounted to more than five million
dollars, of which at least one million [***2] was invested in real
estate owned by the company in fee; at least two millions in bonds of the city
of New York; and at least one million in the bonds and stocks of other
corporations of the United States; that the net profits or income of the
defendant company during the year ending December 31, 1894, amounted to more
than the sum of $300,000 above its actual operating and business expenses,
including losses and interest on bonded and other indebtedness; that from its
real estate the company derived an income of $50,000 per annum, after deducting
all county, state, and municipal taxes; and that the company derived an income
or profit of about $60,000 per annum from its investments in municipal bonds.
It was further alleged that under and by virtue of the powers conferred upon
the company, it had from time to time taken and executed, and was holding and
executing, numerous trusts committed to the company by many persons,
copartnerships, unincorporated associations, and corporations, by grant,
assignment, devise, and bequest, and by orders of various courts, and that the
company now held as trustee for many minors, individuals, copartnerships,
associations, and corporations, resident [***3] in the United
States and elsewhere, many parcels of real estate situated in the various
States of the United States, and amounting, in the aggregate, to a value
exceeding five millions of dollars, the rents and income of which real estate
collected and received by said defendant in its fiduciary capacity annually
exceeded the sum of two hundred thousand dollars.
The bill also averred that complainant was and had been since May 20, 1892, the
owner and registered holder of ten shares of the capital stock of the company,
of a value exceeding the sum of $5000; that the capital stock was divided among
a large number of different persons who as such stockholders constituted a
large body; that the bill was filed for an object common to them all; and that
he, therefore, brought suit, not only in his own behalf as a stockholder of the
company, but also as a representative of and on behalf of such of the other
stockholders similarly situated and interested as might choose to intervene and
become parties.
It was then alleged that the management of the stock, property, affairs, and
concerns of the company was committed under its acts of incorporation to its
directors, and charged that the [***4] company and a majority of
its directors claimed and asserted that under and by virtue of the alleged authority
of the provisions of an act of Congress of the United States entitled, "An
act to reduce taxation, to provide revenue for the government, and for other
purposes," passed August 15, 1894, the company was liable and that they
intended to pay to the United States before July 1, 1895, a tax of two per
centum on the net profits of said company for the year ending December 31,
1894, above actual operating and business expenses, including the income
derived from its real estate and its bonds of the city of New York, and that
the directors claimed and asserted that a similar tax must be paid upon the
amount of the incomes, gains, and profits, in excess of $4000, of all minors
and others for whom the company was acting in a fiduciary capacity. And
further, that the company and its directors had avowed their intention to make
and file with the collector of internal revenue for the second district of the
city of New York a list, return, or statement showing the amount of the net
income of the company received during the year 1894 as aforesaid, and likewise
to make and render a list [***5] or return to said collector of
internal revenue, prior to that date, of the amount of the income, gains, and
profits of all minors and other persons having incomes in excess of $3500, for
whom the company was acting in a fiduciary capacity.
The bill charged that the provisions in respect of said alleged income tax
incorporated in the act of Congress were unconstitutional, null, and void, in
that the tax was a direct tax in respect of the real estate held and owned by
the company in its own right and in its fiduciary capacity as aforesaid, by
being imposed upon the rents, issues, and profits of said real estate, and was
likewise a direct tax in respect of its personal property and the personal
property held by it for others for whom it acted in its fiduciary capacity as
aforesaid, which direct taxes were not in and by said act apportioned among the
several States as required by section 2 of article I of the Constitution; and
that if the income tax so incorporated in the act of Congress aforesaid were
held not to be a direct tax, nevertheless its provisions were unconstitutional,
null, and void in that they were not uniform throughout the United States as
required in and by section [***6] 8 of article I of the
Constitution of the United States, upon many grounds and in many particulars
specifically set forth.
The bill further charged that the income tax provisions of the act were
likewise unconstitutional in that they imposed a tax on incomes not taxable
under the Constitution and likewise income derived from the stocks and bonds of
the States of the United States and counties and municipalities therein, which
stocks and bonds are among the means and instrumentalities employed for carrying
on their respective governments, and are not proper subjects of the taxing
power of Congress, and which States and their counties and municipalities are
independent of the general government of the United States, and the respective
stocks and bonds of which are, together with power of the States to borrow in
any form, exempt from Federal taxation.
Other grounds of unconstitutionality were assigned, and the violation of
articles IV and V of the Constitution asserted.
The bill further averred that the suit was not a collusive one to confer on a
court of the United States jurisdiction of the case, of which it would not
otherwise have cognizance, and that complainant had requested
[***7] the company and its directors to omit and refuse to pay said
income tax, and to contest the constitutionality of said act, and to refrain
from voluntarily making lists, returns, and statements on its own behalf and on
behalf of the minors and other persons for whom it was acting in a fiduciary
capacity, and to apply to a court of competent jurisdiction to determine its
liability under said act, but that the company and a majority of its directors,
after a meeting of the directors, at which the matter and the request of
complainant were formally laid before them for action, had refused and still
refuse, and intend omitting to comply with complainant's demand and had
resolved and determined, and intended to comply with all and singular the
provisions of the said act of Congress, and to pay the tax upon all its net
profits or income as aforesaid, including its rents from real estate and its
income from municipal bonds, and a copy of the refusal of the company was
annexed to the complaint.
It was also alleged that if the company and its directors, as they proposed and
had declared their intention to do, should pay the tax out of its gains,
income, and profits, or out of the gains, income, [***8] and
profits of the property held by it in its fiduciary capacity, they will
diminish the assets of the company and lessen the dividends thereon and the
value of the shares; that voluntary compliance with the income tax provisions
would expose the company to a multiplicity of suits, not only by and on behalf
of its numerous shareholders, but by and on behalf of numerous minors and others
for whom it acts in a fiduciary capacity, and that such numerous suits would
work irreparable injury to the business of the company, and subject it to great
and irreparable damage, and to liabilit to the beneficiaries aforesaid, to the
irreparable damage of complainant and all its shareholders.
The bill further averred that this was a suit of a civil nature in equity; that
the matter in dispute exceeded exclusive of costs the sum of five thousand
dollars, and arose under the Constitution or laws of the United States; and
that there was furthermore a controversy between citizens of different States.
The prayer was that it might be adjudged and decreed that the said provisions
known as the income tax incorporated in said act of Congress passed August 15, 1894,
are unconstitutional, null, and void; [***9] that the defendants be
restrained from voluntarily complying with the provisions of said act, and
making the lists, returns, and statements above referred to, or paying the tax
aforesaid; and for general relief.
The defendants demurred on the ground of want of equity, and the cause having
been brought on to be heard upon the bill and demurrer thereto, the demurrer
was sustained and the bill of complaint dismissed with costs, whereupon the
record recited that the constitutionality of a law of the United States was
drawn in question, and an appeal was allowed directly to this court.
An abstract of the act in question will be found in the margin. n1
n1 By sections 27 to 37 inclusive of the act of Congress entitled "An act
to reduce taxation, to provide revenue for the government, and for other
purposes," received by the President August 15, 1894, and which, not
having been returned by him to the House in which it originated within the time
prescribed by the Constitution of the United States, became a law without
approval, (28 Stat. 509, c. 349,) it was provided that from and after January
1, 1895, and until January 1, 1900, "there shall be assessed, levied,
collected, and paid annually upon the gains, profits, and income received in
the preceding calendar year by every citizen of the United States, whether
residing at home or abroad, and every person residing therein, whether said
gains, profits, or income be derived from any kind of property, rents, interest,
dividends, or salaries, or from any profession, trade, employment, or vocation
carried on in the United States or elsewhere, or from any other source
whatever, a tax of two per centum on the amount so derived over and above four
thousand dollars, and a like tax shall be levied, collected, and paid annually
upon the gains, profits, and income from all property owned and of every
business, trade, or profession carried on in the United States by persons
residing without the United States." . . .
"SEC. 28. That in estimating the gains, profits, and income of any person
there shall be included all income derived from interest upon notes, bonds, and
other securities, except such bonds of the United States the principal and
interest of which are by the law of their issuance exempt from all Federal
taxation; profits realized within the year from sales of real estate purchased
within two years previous to the close of the year for which income is
estimated; interest received or accrued upon all notes, bonds mortgages, or
other forms of indebtedness bearing interest, whether paid or not, if good and
collectible, less the interest which has become due from said person or which
has been paid by him during the year; the amount of all premium on bonds,
notes, or coupons; the amount of sales of live stock, sugar, cotton, wool,
butter, cheese, pork, beef, mutton, or other meats, hay, and grain, or other
vegetable or other productions, being the growth or produce of the estate of
such person, less the amount expended in the purchase or production of said
stock or produce, and not including any part thereof consumed directly by the
family; money and the value of all personal property acquired by gift or
inheritance; all other gains, profits, and income derived from any source
whatever except that portion of the salary compensation, or pay received for
services in the civil, military, naval, or other service of the United States,
including Senators, Representatives, and Delegates in Congress, from which the
tax has been deducted, and except that portion of any salary upon which the
employer is required by law to withhold, and does withhold the tax and pays the
same to the officer authorized to receive it. In computing incomes the
necessary expenses actually incurred in carrying on any business, occupation,
or profession shall be deducted and also all interest due or paid within the
year by such person on existing indebtedness. And all national, state, county,
school, and municipal taxes, not including those assessed against local
benefits, paid within the year shall be deducted from the gains, profits, or
income of the person who has actually paid the same, whether such person be
owner, tenant, or mortgagor; also losses actually sustained during the year,
incurred in trade or arising from fires, storms, or shipwreck, and not
compensated for by insurance or otherwise, and debts ascertained to be
worthless, but excluding all estimated depreciation of values and losses within
the year on sales of real estate purchased within two years previous to the
year for which income is estimated: Provided, That no deduction shall be made
for any amount paid out for new buildings permanent improvements, or
betterments, made to increase the value of any property or estate: Provided
further, That only one deduction of four thousand dollars shall be made from
the aggregate income of all the members of any family, composed of one or both
parents, and one or more minor children, or husband and wife; that guardians
shall be allowed to make a deduction in favor of each and every ward, except
that in case where two or more wards are comprised in one family, and have
joint property interests, the aggregate deduction in their favor shall not
exceed four thousand dollars: And provided further, That in cases where the
salary or other compensation paid to any person in the employment or service of
the United States shall not exceed the rate of four thousand dollars per annum,
or shall be by fees, or uncertain or irregular in the amount or in the time
during which the same shall have accrued or been earned, such salary or other
compensation shall be included in estimating the annual gains, profits, or
income of the person to whom the same shall have been paid, and shall include
that portion of any income or salary upon which a tax has not been paid by the
employer, where the employer is required by law to pay on the excess over four
thousand dollars: Provided also, That in computing the income of any person,
corporation, company, or association there shall not be included the amount
received from any corporation, company, or association as dividends upon the
stock of such corporation, company, or association if the tax of two per centum
has been paid upon its net profits by said corporation, company, or association
as required by this act.
"SEC. 29. That it shall be the duty of all persons of lawful age having an
income of more than three thousand five hundred dollars for the taxable year,
computed on the basis herein prescribed, to make and render a list or return,
on or before the day provided by law, in such form and manner as may be
directed by the Commissioner of Internal Revenue, with the approval of the
Secretary of the Treasury, to the collector or a deputy collector of the
district in which they reside, of the amount of their income, gains, and
profits, as aforesaid; and all guardians and trustees, executors,
administrators, agents, receivers, and all persons or corporations acting in
any fiduciary capacity, shall make and render a list or return as aforesaid, to
the collector or a deputy collector of the district in which such person or
corporation acting in a fiduciary capacity resides or does business, of the
amount of income, gains, and profits of any minor or person for whom they act,
but persons having less than three thousand five hundred dollars income are not
required to make such report; and the collector or deputy collector shall
require every list or return to be verified by the oath or affirmation of the
party rendering it, and may increase the amount of any list or return if he has
reason to believe that the same is understated; and in case any such person
having a taxable income shall neglect or refuse to make and render such list
and return, or shall render a wilfully false or fraudulent list or return, it
shall be the duty of the collector or deputy collector, to make such list,
according to the best information he can obtain, by the examination of such
person, or any other evidence, and to add fifty per centum as a penalty to the
amount of the tax due on such list in all cases of wilful neglect or refusal to
make and render a list or return; and in all cases of a wilfully false or
fraudulent list or return having been rendered to add one hundred per centum as
a penalty to the amount of tax ascertained to be due, the tax and the additions
thereto as a penalty to be assessed and collected in the manner provided for in
other cases of wilful neglect or refusal to render a list or return, or of
rendering a false or fraudulent return." A proviso was added that any
person or corporation might show that he or its ward had no taxable income, or
that the same had been paid elsewhere, and the collector might exempt from the
tax for that year. "Any person or company, corporation, or association,
feeling aggrieved by the decision of the deputy collector, in such cases may
appeal to the collector of the district, and his decision thereon, unless
reversed by the Commissioner of Internal Revenue, shall be final. If
dissatisfied with the decision of the collector such person or corporation,
company, or association may submit the case, with all the papers, to the
Commissioner of Internal Revenue for his decision, and may furnish the
testimony of witnesses to prove any relevant facts having served notice to that
effect upon the Commissioner of Internal Revenue, as herein prescribed."
Provision was made for notice of time and place for taking testimony on both
sides, and that no penalty should be assessed until after notice.
By section 30 the taxes on incomes were made payable on or before July 1 of
each year, and five per cent penalty levied on taxes unpaid, and interest.
By section 31, any non-resident might receive the benefit of the exemptions
provided for, and "in computing income he shall include all income from
every source, but unless he be a citizen of the United States he shall only pay
on that part of the income which is derived from any source in the United
States. In case such non-resident fails to file such statement, the collector
of each district shall collect the tax on the income derived from property
situated in his district, subject to income tax, making no allowance for
exemptions, and all property belonging to such non-resident shall be liable to
distraint for tax: Provided, That non-resident corporations shall be subject to
the same laws as to tax as resident corporations, and the collection of the tax
shall be made in the same manner as provided for collections of taxes against
non-resident persons."
"SEC. 32. That there shall be assessed, levied, and collected, except as
herein otherwise provided, a tax of two per centum annually on the net profits
or income above actual operating and business expenses, including expenses for
materials purchased for manufacture or bought for resale, losses, and interest
on bonded and other indebtedness of all banks, banking institutions, trust
companies, saving institutions, fire, marine, life, and other insurance
companies, railroad, canal, turnpike, canal navigation, slack water, telephone,
telegraph, express, electric light, gas, water, street railway companies, and
all other corporations, companies, or associations doing business for profit in
the United States, no matter how created and organized but not including
partnerships."
The tax is made payable "on or before the first day of July in each year;
and if the president or other chief officer of any corporation, company, or
association, or in the case of any foreign corporation, company, or
association, the resident manager or agent shall neglect or refuse to file with
the collector of the internal revenue district in which said corporation,
company, or association shall be located or be engaged in business, a statement
verified by his oath or affirmation, in such form as shall be prescribed by the
Commissioner of Internal Revenue, with the approval of the Secretary of the
Treasury, showing the amount of net profits or income received by said
corporation, company, or association during the whole calendar year last
preceding the date of filing said statement as hereinafter required, the
corporation, company, or association making default shall forfeit as a penalty
the sum of one thousand dollars and two per centum on the amount of taxes due,
for each month until the same is paid, the payment of said penalty to be
enforced as provided in other cases of neglect and refusal to make return of
taxes under the internal revenue laws.
"The net profits or income of all corporations, companies, or associations
shall include the amounts paid to shareholders, or carried to the account of
any fund, or used for construction, enlargement of plant, or any other
expenditure or investment paid from the net annual profits made or acquired by
said corporations, companies, or associations.
"That nothing herein contained shall apply to States, counties, or
municipalities; nor to corporations, companies, or associations organized and
conducted solely for charitable, religious, or educational purposes, including
fraternal beneficiary societies, orders, or associations operating upon the
lodge system and providing for the payment of life, sick, accident, and other
benefits to the members of such societies, orders, or associations and
dependents of such members; nor to the stocks, shares, funds, or securities
held by any fiduciary or trustee for charitable, religious, or educational
purposes; nor to building and loan associations or companies which make loans
only to their shareholders; nor to such savings banks savings institutions or
societies as shall, first, have no stockholders or members except depositors
and no capital except deposits; secondly, shall not receive deposits to an
aggregate amount, in any one year, of more than one thousand dollars from the
same depositor; thirdly, shall not allow an accumulation or total of deposits,
by any one depositor, exceeding ten thousand dollars; fourthly, shall actually
divide and distribute to its depositors, ratably to deposits, all the earnings
over the necessary and proper expenses of such bank, institution, or society,
except such as shall be applied to surplus; fifthly, shall not possess, in any
form, a surplus fund exceeding ten per centum of its aggregate deposits; nor to
such savings banks, savings institutions, or societies composed of members who
do not participate in the profits thereof and which pay interest or dividends
only to their depositors; nor to that part of the business of any savings bank,
institution, or other similar association having a capital stock, that is
conducted on the mutual plan solely for the benefit of its depositors on such
plan, and which shall keep its accounts of its business conducted on such
mutual plan separate and apart from its other accounts.
"Nor to any insurance company or association which conducts all its
business solely upon the mutual plan, and only for the benefit of its policy
holders or members, and having no capital stock and no stock or shareholders,
and holding all its property in trust and in reserve for its policy holders or
members; nor to that part of the business of any insurance company having a
capital stock and stock and shareholders, which is conducted on the mutual
plan, separate from its stock plan of insurance, and solely for the benefit of
the policy holders and members insured on said mutual plan, and holding all the
property belonging to and derived from said mutual part of its business in
trust and reserve for the benefit of its policy holders and members insured on
said mutual plan.
"That all state, county, municipal, and town taxes paid by corporations,
companies, or associations, shall be included in the operating and business
expenses of such corporations, companies, or associations.
"SEC. 33. That there shall be levied, collected, and paid on all salaries
of officers, or payments for services to persons in the civil, military, naval,
or other employment or service of the United States, including Senators and
Representatives and Delegates in Congress, when exceeding the rate of four
thousand dollars per annum, a tax of two per centum on the excess above the
said four thousand dollars; and it shall be the duty of all paymasters and all
disbursing officers under the government of the United States, or persons in
the employ thereof, when making any payment to any officers or persons as
aforesaid, whose compensation is determined by a fixed salary, or upon settling
or adjusting the accounts of such officers or persons, to deduct and withhold
the aforesaid tax of two per centum; and the pay roll, receipts, or account of
officers or persons paying such tax as aforesaid shall be made to exhibit the
fact of such payment. And it shall be the duty of the accounting officers of
the Treasury Department, when auditing the accounts of any paymaster or
disbursing officer, or any officer withholding his salary from moneys received
by him, or when settling or adjusting the accounts of any such officer, to
require evidence that the taxes mentioned in this section have been deducted
and paid over to the Treasurer of the United States, or other officer
authorized to receive the same. Every corporation which pays to any employe a
salary or compensation exceeding four thousand dollars per annum shall report
the same to the collector or deputy collector of his district and said employe
shall pay thereon, subject to the exemptions herein provided for, the tax of
two per centum on the excess of his salary over four thousand dollars:
Provided, That salaries due to state, county, or municipal officers shall be
exempt from the income tax herein levied."
By section 34, sections thirty-one hundred and sixty-seven, thirty-one hundred
and seventy-two, thirty-one hundred and seventy-three, and thirty-one hundred
and seventy-six of the Revised Statutes of the United States as amended were
amended so as to provide that it should be unlawful for the collector and other
officers to make known, or to publish amount or source of income under penalty;
that every collector should "from time to time cause his deputies to
proceed through every part of his district and inquire after and concerning all
persons therein who are liable to pay any internal revenue tax, and all persons
owning or having the care and management of any objects liable to pay any tax,
and to make a list of such persons and enumerate said objects;" that the
tax returns must be made on or before the first Monday in March; that the
collectors may make returns when particulars are furnished; that notice be
given to absentees to render returns; that collectors may summon persons to
produce books and testify concerning returns; that collectors may enter other
districts to examine persons and books; and may make returns; and that
penalties may be imposed on false returns.
By section 35 it was provided that corporations doing business for profit
should make returns on or before the first Monday of March of each year
"of all the following matters for the whole calendar year last preceding
the date of such return:
"First. The gross profits of such corporation, company, or association,
from all kinds of business of every name and nature.
"Second. The expenses of such corporation, company, or association,
exclusive of interest, annuities, and dividend.
"Third. The net profits of such corporation, company, or association,
without allowance for interest, annuities, or dividends.
"Fourth. The amount paid on account of interest, annuities, and dividends,
stated separately.
"Fifth. The amount paid in salaries of four thousand dollars or less to
each person employed.
"Sixth. The amount paid in salaries of more than four thousand dollars to
each person employed and the name and address of each of such persons and the
amount paid to each."
By section 36, that books of account should be kept by corporations as
prescribed, and inspection thereof be granted under penalty.
By section 37 provision is made for receipts for taxes paid.
By a joint resolution of February 21, 1895, the time for making returns of
income for the year 1894 was extended, and it was provided that "in
computing incomes under said act the amounts necessarily paid for fire
insurance premiums and for ordinary repairs shall be deducted;" and that
"in computing incomes under said act the amounts received as dividends
upon the stock of any corporation, company, or association shall not be
included in case such dividends are also liable to the tax of two per centum
upon the net profits of said corporation, company, or association although such
tax may not have been actually paid by said corporation, company, or
association at the time of making returns by the person, corporation, or association
receiving such dividends, and returns or reports of the names and salaries of
employes shall not be required from employers unless called for by the
collector in order to verify the returns of employes." [***10]
By the third clause of section two of Article I of the Constitution it was
provided: "Representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned among the
several States which may be included within this Union, according to their
respective numbers, which shall be determined by adding to the whole number of
free persons, including those bound to service for a term of years, and
excluding Indians not taxed, three-fifths of all other persons." This was
amended by the second section of the Fourteenth Article, declared ratified July
28, 1868, so that the whole number of persons in each State should be counted,
Indians not taxed excluded, and the provision as thus amended, remains in
force.
The actual enumeration was prescribed to be made within three years after the
first meeting of Congress and within every subsequent term of ten years, in
such manner as should be directed.
Section 7 requires "all bills for raising revenue shall originate in the
House of Representatives."
The first clause of section 8 reads thus: "The Congress shall have power to
lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and excise, to pay the debts and
provide for the common defence and general welfare of the United
[***11] States; but all duties, imposts and excises shall be
uniform throughout the United States." And the third clause thus: "To
regulate commerce with foreign nations, and among the several States, and with
the Indian tribes."
The fourth, fifth, and sixth clauses of section 9 are as follows:
"No capitation, or other direct, tax shall be laid, unless in proportion
to the census or enumeration hereinbefore directed to be taken.
"No tax or duty shall be laid on articles exported from any State.
"No preference shall be given by any regulation of commerce or revenue to
the ports of one State over those of another; nor shall vessels bound to, or
from, one State, be obliged to enter, clear, or pay duties in another."
It is also provided by the second clause of section 10 that "no State
shall, without the consent of the Congress, lay any imposts or duties on imports
or exports, except what may be absolutely necessary for executing its
inspection laws;" and, by the third clause, that "no State shall,
without the consent of Congress, lay any duty of tonnage."
The first clause of section 9 provides: "The migration or importation of
such persons as any of the States now existing shall think [***12]
proper to admit, shall not be prohibited by the Congress prior to the year one
thousand eight hundred and eight, but a tax or duty may be imposed on such importations,
not exceeding ten dollars for each person.
Article V prescribes the mode for the amendment of the Constitution, and
concludes with this proviso: "Provided that no amendment which may be made
prior to the year one thousand eight hundred and eight shall in any manner
affect the first and fourth clauses in the ninth section of the first
article."
OPINION:
[*553] [**679] MR. CHIEF JUSTICE FULLER, after stating
the case as above reported, delivered the opinion of the court:
The jurisdiction of a court of equity to prevent any threatened breach of trust
in the misapplication or diversion of [***221] the funds of a
corporation by illegal payments out of its capital or profits has been
frequently sustained. Dodge v. woolsey, 18 How. 331; Hawes v. Oakland, 104 U.S.
450.
[*554] As in Dodge v. Woolsey, this bill proceeds on the ground
that the defendants would be guilty of such breach of trust or duty in
voluntarily making retfurns for the imposition of, and paying, an
unconstitutional tax; and also on allegations of threatened multiplicity of
suits and irreparable injury.
The objection of adequate remedy at law was not raised below, nor is it now
raised by appellees, if it could be entertained at all at this stage of the
proceedings; and, so far as it was within the power of the government to do so,
the question of jurisdiction, for the purposes of the case, was explicitly
waived on the argument. The relief sought was in respect of voluntary action by
the defendant company, and not in respect of the assessment and collection
themselves. Under these circumstances, we should not be justified in declining
to proceed to judgment upon the merits. Pelton v. National Bank, 101 U.S. 143,
148; Cummings v. National Bank, 101 U.S. 153, 157; Reynes v. Dumont, 130 U.S.
[***222] 354.
Since the opinion in Marbury v. Madison, 1 Cranch, 137, 177, was delivered, it
has not been doubted that it is within judicial competency, by express
provisions of the Constitution or by necessary inference and implication, to
determine whether a given law of the United States is or is not made in
pursuance of the Constitution, and to hold it valid or void accordingly.
"If," said Chief Justice Marshall, "both the law and the
Constitution apply to a particular case, so that the court must either decide
that case conformably to the law, disregarding the Constitution; or conformably
to the Constitution, disregarding the law; the court must determine which of
these conflicting rules governs the case. This is of the very essence of
judicial duty." And the Chief Justice added that the doctrine "that
courts must close their eyes on the Constitution, and see only the law,"
"would subvert the very foundation of all written constitutions."
Necessarily the power to declare a law unconstitutional is always exercised
with reluctance; but the duty to do so, in a proper case, cannot be declined,
and must be discharged in accordance with the deliberate judgment of the
tribunal in which the [***223] validity of the enactment is
directly drawn in question.
[*555] The contention of the complainant is:
First. That the law in question, in imposing a tax on the income or rents of
real estate, imposes a tax upon the real estate itself; and in imposing a tax
on the interest or other income of bonds or other personal property held for
the purposes of income or ordinarily yielding income, imposes a tax upon the
personal estate itself; that such tax is a direct tax, and void because imposed
without regard to the rule of apportionment; and that by reason thereof the
whole law is invalidated.
Second. That the law is invalid, because imposing indirect taxes in violation
of the constitutional requirement of uniformity; and therein also in violation
of the implied limitation upon taxation that all tax laws must apply equally,
impartially, and uniformly to all similarly situated. Under the second head it
is contended that the rule of uniformity is violated in that the law taxes the
income of certain corporations, companies, and associations, no matter how
created or organized, at a higher rate than the incomes of individuals or
partfnerships derived from precisely similar property [***224] or
business; in that it exempts from the operation of the act and from the burden
of taxation, numerous corporations, companies, and associations having similar
property and carrying on similar business to those expressly taxed; in that it
denies to individuals deriving their income from shares in certain
corporations, companies, and associations the benefit of the exemption of $
4000 granted to other persons [**680] interested in similar property
and business; in the exemption of $ 4000; in the exemfption of building and
loan associations, savings banks, mutual life, fire, marine, and accident
insurance companies, existing solely for the pecuniary profit of their members;
these and other exemptions being alleged to be purely arbitrary and capricious,
justified by no public purpose, and of such magnitude as to invalidate the
entire enactment; and in other particulars.
Third. That the law is invalid so far as imposing a tax upon income received
from state and municipal bonds.
The Constitution provides that representatives and direct [*556]
taxes shall be apportioned among the several States according to numbers, and
that no direct tax shall be laid except according to the [***225]
enumeration provided for; and also that all duties, imposts and excises shall
be uniform throughout the United States.
The men who framed and adopted that instrument had just emerged from the
struggle for independence whose rallying cry had been that "taxation and
representation gof together."
The mother country had taught the colonists, in the contests waged to establish
that taxes could not be imposed by the sovereign except as they were granted by
the representatives of the realm, that self-taxation constituted the main
security against oppression. As Burke declared, in his speech on Conciliation
with America, the defenders of the excellence of the English constitution
"took infinite pains to inclucate, as a fundamental principle, that, in
all monarchies, the people must, in effect, themselves, mediately or
immediately, possess the power of granting their own money, or on shadow of
liberty could subsist." The principle was that the consent of those who
were expected to pay it was essential tof the validity of any tax.
The States were about, for all national purposes embraced in the Constitution,
to become one, united under the same sovereign authority, and governed by the
[***226] same laws. But as they still retained their jurisdiction
over all persons and things within their territforial limits, except where
surrendered to the general government or restrained by the Constitution, they
were careful to see to it that taxation and representation should go together,
so that the sovereignty reserved should not be impaired, and that when
Congress, and especially the House of Representatives, where it was
specifically provided that all revenue bills must originate, voted a tax upon
property, it should be with the consciousness, and under the responsibility,
that in so doing the tax so voted would proportionately fall upon the immediate
constituents of those who imposed it.
More than this, by the Constitution the States not only gave to the Nation the
concurrent power to tax persons and [*557] property directly, but
they surrendered their own power to levy taxes on imports and to regulate
commerce. All the thirteen were seaboard States, but they varied in maritime
importance, and differences existed between them in population, in wealth, in
the character of property and of business interests. Moreover, they looked
forward to the coming of new [***227] States from the great West
into the vast empire of their anticipations. So when the wealthier States as
between themselves and their less favored associates, and all as between
themselves and their less favored associates, and all as between themselves and
those who were to come, gave up for the common good the great sources of
revenue derived through commerce, they did so in reliance on the protection
afforded by restrictions on the grant of power.
Thus, in the matter of taxation, the Constitution recognizes the two great
classes of direct and indirect taxes, and lays down two rules by which their
imposition must be governed, namely: The rule of apportionment as to direct taxes,
and the rule of uniformity as to duties, imposts and excises.
The rule of uniformity was not prescribed to the exercise of the power granted
by the first paragraph of section eight, to lay and collect taxes, because the
rule of apportionment as to taxes had already been laid down in the third
paragraph of the second section.
And this view was expressed by Mr. Chief Justice Chase in The License Tax
Cases, 5 Wall. 462, 471, when he said: "It is true that the power of
Congress to tax is a very extensive [***228] power. It is given in
the Constitution, with only one exception and only two qualifications. Congress
cannot tax exports, and it must impose direct taxes by the rule of
apportionment, and indirect taxes by the rule of uniformity. Thus limited, and
thus only, it reaches every subject, and may be exercised at discretion."
And although there have been from time to time intimations that there might be
some tax which was not a direct tax nor included under the words "duties,
imposts and excises," such a tax for more than one hundred years of
national existence has as yet remained undiscovered, notwithstanding the stress
of particular circumstances has invited thorough investigation into sources of
revenue.
[*558] The first question to be considered is whether a tax on the
rents or income of real estate is a direct tax within the meaning of the
Constitution. Ordinarily all taxes paid primarily by persons who can shift the
burden upon some one else, or who are under no legal compulsion to pay them,
are considered indirect taxes; but a tax upon property holders in respect of
their estates, whether real or personal, or of the income yielded by such
estates, and the payment of which [***229] cannot be avoided, are
direct taxes. Nevertheless, it may be admitted that although this definition of
direct taxes is prima facie correct, and to be applied in the consideration of
the question before us, yet that the Constitution may bear a different meaning,
and that such different meaning must be recognized. But in arriving at any
conclusion upon this point, we are at [**681] liberty to refer to
the historical circumstances attending the framing and adoption of the
Constitution as well as the entire frame and scheme of the instrument, and the consequences
naturally attendant upon the one construction or the other.
We inquire, therefore, what, at the time the Constitution was framed and
adopted, were recognized as direct taxes? What did those who framed and adopted
it understand the terms to designate and include?
We must remember that the fifty-five members of the constitutional convention
were men of great sagacity, fully conversant with governmental problems, deeply
conscious of the nature of their task, and profoundly convinced that they were
laying the foundations of a vast future empire. "To many in the assembly
the work of the great French magistrate on the 'Spirit [***230] of
Laws,' of which Washington with his own hand had copied an abstract by Madison,
was the favorite manual; some of them had made an analysis of all federal
governments in ancient and modern times, and a few were well versed in the best
English, Swiss, and Dutch writers on government. They had immediately before
them the example of Great Britain; and they had a still better school of
political wisdom in the republican constitutions of their several States, which
many of them had assisted to frame." 2 Bancroft's Hist. Const. 9.
The Federalist demonstrates the value attached by Hamilton, [*559]
Madison, and Jay to historical experience, and shows that they had made a
careful study of many forms of government. Many of the framers were
particularly versed in the literature of the period, Franklin, Wilson, and
Hamilton for example. Turgot had published in 1764 his work on taxation, and in
1766 his essay on "The Formation and Distribution of Wealth," while
Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations" was published in 1776. Franklin in
1766 had said upon his examination before the House of Commons that: "An
external tax is a duty laid on commodities imported; that duty is added to the
first [***231] cost and other charges on the commodity, and, when
it is offered to sale makes a part of the price. If the people do not like it
at that price, they refuse it; they are not obliged to pay it. But an internal
tax is forced from the people without their consent, if not laid by their own
representatives. The stamp act says, we shall have no commerce, make no
exchange of property with each other, neither purchase nor grant, nor recover
debts; we shall neither marry nor make our wills, unless we pay such and such
sums; and thus it is intended to extort our money from us, or ruin us by the
consequences of refusing to pay." 16 Parl. Hist. 144.
They were, of course, familiar with the modes of taxation pursued in the
several States. From the report of Oliver Wolcott, when Secretary of the
Treasury, on direct taxes, to the House of Representatives, December 14, 1796,
his most important state paper, (Am. State Papers, 1 Finance, 431,) and the
various state laws then existing, it appears that prior to the adoption of the
Constitution nearly all the States imposed a poll tax, taxes on land, on cattle
of all kinds, and various kinds of personal property, and that, in addition,
Massachusetts, [***232] Connecticut, Pennsylvania, Delaware, New
Jersey, Virginia, and South Carolina assessed their citizens upon their profits
from professions, trades, and employments.
Congress under the articles of confederation had no actual operative power of
taxation. It could call upon the States for their respective contributions or
quotas as previously determined on; but in case of the failure or omission of
the States to furnish such contribution, there were no means of
[*560] compulsion, as Congress had no power whatever to lay any tax
upon individuals. This imperatively demanded a remedy; but the opposition to
granting the power of direct taxation in addition to the substantially
exclusive power of laying imposts and duties was so strong that it required the
convention, in securing effective powers of taxation to the Federal government,
to use the utmost care and skill to so harmonize conflicting interests that the
ratification of the instrument could be obtained.
The situation and the result are thus described by Mr. Chief Justice Chase in
Lane County v. Oregon, 7 Wall. 71, 76: "The people of the United States
constitute one nation, under one government, and this government,
[***233] within the scope of the powers with which it is invested,
is supreme. On the other hand, the people of each State compose a State, having
its own government, and endowed with all the functions essential to separate
and independent existence. The States disunited might continue to exist.
Without the States in union there could be no such political body as the United
States. Both the States and the United States existed before the Constitution.
The people, through that instrument, established a more perfect union by
substituting a national government, acting, with ample power, directly upon the
citizens, instead of the confederate government, which acted with powers,
greatly restricted, only upon the States. But in many articles of the
Constitution the necessary existence of the States, and within their proper
spheres, the independent authority of the States, is distinctly recognized. To
them nearly the whole charge of interior regulation is committed or left; to
them and to the people all powers not expressly delegated to the national
government are reserved. The general condition was well stated by Mr. Madison
in the Federalist, thus: 'The Federal and state governments are
[***234] in fact but different agents and trustees of the people,
constituted with different powers and designated for different purposes.' Now,
to the existence of the States, themselves necessary [**682] to the
existence of the United States, the power of taxation is indispensable. It is
an essential function of [*561] government. It was exercised by the
colonies; and when the colonies became States, both before and after the
formation of the confederation, it was exercised by the new governments. Under
the Articles of Confederation the government of the United States was limited
in the exercise of this power to requisitions upon the States, while the whole
power of direct and indirect taxation of persons and property, whether by taxes
on polls, or duties on imports, or duties on internal production, manufacture,
or use, was acknowledged to belong exclusively to the States, without any other
limitation than that of non-interference with certain treaties made by
Congress. The Constitution, it is true, grantly changed this condition of
things. It gave the power to tax, both directly and indirectly, to the national
government, and subject to the one prohibition of any tax upon [***235]
exports and to the conditions of uniformity in respect to indirect and of
proportion in respect to direct taxes, the power was given without any express
reservation. On the other hand, no power to tax exports, or imports except for
a single purpose and to an insignificant extent, or to lay any duty on tonnage,
was permitted to the States. In respect, however, to property, business, and
persons, within their respective limits, their power of taxation remained and
remains entire. It is indeed a concurrent power, and in the case of a tax on
the same subject by both governments, the claim of the United States, as the
supreme authority, must be preferred; but with this qualification it is
absolute. The extent to which it shall be exercised, the subjects upon which it
shall be exercised, and the mode in which it shall be exercised, are all
equally within the discretion of the legislatures to which the States commit
the exercise of the power. That discretion is restrained only by the will of
the people expressed in the state constitutions or through elections, and by
the condition that it must not be so used as to burden or embarrass the
operations of the national government. There [***236] is nothing in
the Constitution which contemplates or authorizes any direct abridgment of this
power by national legislation. To the extent just indicated it is as complete
in the States as the like [*562] power, within the limits of the
Constitution, is complete in Congress."
On May 29, 1787, Charles Pinckney presented his draft of a proposed
constitution, which provided that the proportion of direct taxes should be
regulated by the whole number of inhabitants of every description, taken in the
manner prescribed by the legislature; and that no tax should be paid on articles
exported from the United States.1 Elliot, 147, 148.
Mr. Randolph's plan declared "that the right of suffrage, in the national
legislature, ought to be proportioned to the quotas of contribution, or to the
number of free inhabitants, as the one or the other may seem best, in different
cases." 1 Elliot, 143.
On June 15, Mr. Paterson submitted several resolutions, among which was one
proposing that the United States in Congress should be authorized to make
requisitions in proportion to the whole number of white and other free citizens
and inhabitants, including those bound to servitude for a term of years,
[***237] and three-fifths of all other persons, except Indians not
taxed. 1 Elliot, 175, 176.
On the ninth of July the proposition that the legislature be authorized to
regulate the number of representatives according to wealth and inhabitants was
approved, and on the eleventh it was voted that "in order to ascertain the
alterations that may happen in the population and wealth of the several States,
a census shall be taken;" although the resolution of which this formed a
part was defeated. 5 Elliot (Madison Papers), 288, 295; 1 Elliot, 200.
On July 12, Gouverneur Morris moved to add to the clause empowering the
legislature to vary the representation according to the amount of wealth and
number of the inhabitants, a proviso that taxation should be in proportion to
representation, and admitting that some objections lay against his proposition,
which would be removed by limiting it to direct taxation, since "with
regard to indirect taxes on exports and imports, and on consumption, the rule
would be inapplicable," varied his motion by inserting the word
"direct," whereupon it passed as follows: "Provided, always,
that direct taxation [*563] ought to be proportioned to
representation." [***238] 5 Elliot (Madison Papers), 302.
Amendments were proposed by Mr. Ellsworth and Mr. Wilson to the effect that the
rule of contribution by direct taxation should be according to the number of
white inhabitants and three-fifths of every other description, and that in
order to ascertain the alterations in the direct taxation which might be
required from time to time a census should be taken; the word wealth was struck
out of the clause, on motion of Mr. Randolph; and the whole proposition,
proportionate representation to direct taxation, and both to the white and
three-fifths of the colored inhabitants, and requiring a census, was adopted.
In the course of the debates, and after the motion of Mr. Ellsworth that the
first census be taken in three years after the meeting of Congress had been
adopted, Mr. Madison records: "Mr. King asked what was the precise meaning
of direct taxation. No one answered." But Mr. Gerry immediately moved to
amend by the insertion of the clause that "from the first meeting of the
legislature of the United States until a census shall be taken, all moneys for
supplying the public treasury by direct taxation shall be raised from the
several States according [***239] to the number [**683]
of their representatives respectively in the first branch." This left for
the time the matter of collection to the States. Mr. Langdon objected that this
would bear unreasonably hard against New Hampshire, and Mr. Martin said that
direct taxation should not be used but in cases of absolute necessity, and then
the States would be the best judges of the mode. 5 Elliot (Madison Papers),
451, 453.
Thus was accomplished one of the great compromises of the Constitution, resting
on the doctrine that the right of representation ought to be conceded to every
community on which a tax is to be imposed, but crystallizing it in such form as
to allay jealousies in respect of the future balance of power; to reconcile
conflicting views in respect of the enumeration of slaves; and to remove the
objection that, in adjusting a system of representation between the States,
regard should be had to their relative wealth, since those who were to be most
heavily [*564] taxed ought to have a proportionate influence in the
government.
The compromise, in embracing the power of direct taxation, consisted not simply
in including part of the slaves in the enumeration of population,
[***240] but in providing that as between State and State such
taxation should be proportioned to representation. The establishment of the
same rule for the apportionment of taxes as for regulating the proportion of
representatives, observed Mr. Madison in No. 54 of the Federalist, was by no
means founded on the same principle, for as to the former it had reference to
the proportion of wealth, and although in respect of that it was in ordinary
cases a very unfit measure, it "had too recently obtained the general
sanction of America, not to have found a ready preference with the
convention," while the opposite interests of the States, balanceing each
other, would produce impartiality in enumeration. By prescribing this rule,
Hamilton wrote (Federalist, No. 36) that the door was shut "to partiality
or oppression," and "the abuse of this power of taxation to have been
provided against with guarded circumspection;" and obviously the operation
of direct taxation on every State tended to prevent resport to that mode of
supply except under pressure of necessity and to promote prudence and economy
in expenditure.
We repeat that the right of the Federal government to directly assess and
collect [***241] its own taxes, at least until after requisitions
upon the States had been made and failed, was one of the chief points of
conflict, and Massachusetts, in ratifying, recommended the adoption of an
amendment in these words: "That Congress do not lay direct taxes but when
the moneys arising from the impost and excise are insufficient for the public
exigencies, nor then until Congress shall have first made a requisition upon
the States to assess, levy, and pay, their respective proportions of such
requisition, agreeably to the census fixed in the said Constitution, in such
way and manner as the legislatures of the States shall think best." 1
Elliot, 322. And in this South Carolina, New York, New Hampshire, and Rhode
Island concurred. Id. 325, 326, 329, 336.
[*565] Luther Martin, in his well-known communication to the
legislature of Maryland in January, 1788, expressed his views thus: "By
the power to lay and collect taxes, they may proceed to direct taxation on
every individual, either by a capitation tax on their heads, or an assessment
on their property. . . . Many of the members, and myself in the number, thought
that states were much better judges of the circumstances of
[***242] their citizens, and what sum of money could be collected
from them by direct taxation, and of the manner in which it could be raised
with the greatest ease and convenience to their citizens, than the general
government could be; and that the general government ought not to have the
power of laying direct taxes in any case but in that of the delinquency of a
State." 1 Elliot, 344, 368, 369.
Ellsworth and Sherman wrote the governor of Connecticut, September 26, 1787,
that it was probable "that the principal branch of revenue will be duties
on imports. What may be necessary to be raised by direct taxation is to be
apportioned on the several States, according to the number of their
inhabitants; and although Congress may raise the money by their own authority,
if necessary, yet that authority need not be exercised, if each State will
furnish its quota." 1 Elliot, 492.
And Ellsworth, in the Connecticut convention, in discussing the power of
Congress to lay taxes, pointed out that all sources of revenue, excepting the
impost, still lay open to the States, and insisted that it was "necessary
that the power of the general legislature should extend to all the objects of
taxation, that government [***243] should be able to command all
the resources of the country; because no man can tell what our exigencies may
be. Wars have now become rather wars of the purse than of the sword. Government
must therefore be able to command the whole power of the purse. . . . Direct
taxation can go but little way towards raising a revenue. To raise money in
this way, people must be provident; they must constantly be laying up money to
answer the demands of the collector. But you cannot make people thus provident.
If you would do anything to the purpose, you must come in when they are
spending, and take a part with them. . . . [*566] All nations have
been the necessity and propriety of raising a revenue by indirect taxation, by
duties upon articles of consumption. . . . In England, the whole public revenue
is about twelve millions sterling per annum. The land tax amounts to about two
millions; the window and some other taxes, to about two millions more. The
other eight millions are raised upon articles [**684] of
consumption. . . . This Constitution defines the extent of the powers of the
general government. If the general legislature should at any time overleap
their limits, [***244] the judicial department is a constitutional
check. If the United States go beyond their powers, if they make a law which
the Constitution does not authorize, it is void; and the judicial power, the
national judges, who, to secure their impartiality, are to be made independent,
will declare it to be void." 2 Elliot, 191, 192, 196.
In the convention of Massachusetts by which the Constitution was ratified, the
second section of article I being under consideration, Mr. King said: "It
is a principle of this Constitution, that representation and taxation should go
hand in hand. . . . By this rule are representation and taxation to be apportioned.
And it was adopted, because it was the language of all America. According to
the confederation, ratified in 1781, the sums for the general welfare and
defence should be apportioned according to the surveyed lands, and improvements
thereon, in the several States; but that it hath never been in the power of
Congress to follow that rule, the returns from the several states being so very
imperfect." 2 Elliot, 36.
Theophilus Parsons observed: "Congress have only a concurrent right with
each State, in laying direct taxes, not an exclusive right;
[***245] and the right of each State to direct taxation is equally
extensive and perfect as the right of Congress." Id. 93. And John Adams,
Dawas, Sumner, King, and Sedgwick all agreed that a direct tax would be the
last source of revenue resorted to by Congress.
In the New York convention, Chancellor Livingston pointed out that when the
imposts diminished and the expenses of the government increased, "they
must have recourse to direct [*567] taxes; that is, taxes on land,
and specific duties." 2 Elliot, 341. And Mr. Jay, in reference to an
amendment that direct taxes should not be imposed until requisition had been
made and proved fruitless, argued that the amendment would involve great
difficulties, and that it ought to be considered that direct taxes were of two
kinds, general and specific. Id. 380, 381.
In Virginia, Mr. John Marshall said: "The objects of direct taxes are well
understood; they are but few; what are they? Lands, slaves, stock of all kinds,
and a few other articles of domestic property. . . . They will have the benefit
of the knowledge and experience of the state legislature. They will see in what
manner the legislature of Virginia collects its taxes. . . .
[***246] Cannot Congress regulate the taxes so as to be equal on
all parts of the community? Where is the absurdity of having thirteen revenues?
Will they clash with, or injure, each other? If not, why cannot Congress make
thirteen distinct laws, and impose the taxes on the general objects of taxation
in each State, so as that all persons of the society shall pay equally, as they
ought?" 3 Elliot, 229, 235. At that time, in Virginia, lands were taxed,
and specific taxes assessed on certain specified objects. These objects were stated
by Secretary Wolcott to be taxes on lands, houses in towns, slaves, stud
horses, jackasses, other horses and mules, billiard tables, four-wheel riding
carriages, phaetons, stage wagons, and riding carriages with two wheels; and it
was undoubtedly to these objects that the future Chief Justice referred.
Mr. Randolph said: "But in this new Constitution, there is a more just and
equitable rule fixed -- a limitation beyond which they cannot go.
Representatives and taxes go hand in hand; according to the one will the other
be regulated. The number of representatives is determined by the number of
inhabitants; they have nothing to do but to lay taxes accordingly."
[***247] 3 Elliot, 121.
Mr. George Nicholas said: "the proportion of taxes is fixed by the number
of inhabitants, and not regulated by the extent of territory, or fertility of
soil. . . . Each State [*568] will know, from its population, its
proportion of any general tax.As it was justly observed by the gentleman over
the way, (Mr. Randolph), they cannot possibly exceed that proportion; they are
limited and restrained expressly to it. The state legislatures have no check of
this kind. Their power is uncontrolled." 3 Elliot, 243, 244.
Mr. Madison remarked that "they will be limited to fix the proportion of
each State, and they must raise it in the most convenient and satisfactory
manner to the public." 3 Elliot, 255.
From these references, and they might be extended indefinitely, it is clear
that the rule to govern each of the great classes into which taxes were divided
was prescribed in view of the commonly accepted distinction between them and of
the taxes directly levied under the systems of the States. And that the
difference between direct and indirect taxation was fully appreciated is supported
by the congressional debates after the government was organized.
In the debates [***248] in the House of Representatives preceding
the passage of the act of Congress to lay "duties upon carriages for the
conveyance of persons," approved June 5, 1794, (1 Stat. 373, c. 45,) Mr.
Sedgwick said that "a capitation tax, and taxes on land and on property
and income generally, were direct charges, as well in the immediate as ultimate
sources of contribution. He had considered those, and those only, as direct taxes
in their operation and effects. On the other hand, a tax imposed on a specific
article of personal property, and particularly if objects of luxury, as in the
case under consideration, he had never supposed had been considered a direct
tax, within the meaning of the Constitution."
Mr. Dexter observed that his colleague "had stated the meaning of direct
taxes to be a [**685] capitation tax, or a general tax on all the
taxable property of the citizens; and that a gentleman from Virginia (Mr.
Nicholas) thought the meaning was, that all taxes are direct which are paid by
the citizen without being recompensed by the consumer; but that, where the tax
was only advanced and repaid by the consumer, the tax was indirect. He thought
that both opinions were just, [***249] [*569] and not
inconsistent, though the gentlemen had differed about them. He thought that a
general tax on all taxable property was a direct tax, because it was paid
without being recompensed by the consumer." Annals 3d Congress, 644, 646.
At a subsequent day of the debate, Mr. Madison objected to the tax on carriages
as "an unconstitutional tax," but Fisher Ames declared that he had
satisfied himself that it was not a direct tax, as "the duty falls not on
the possession but on the use." Annals, 730.
Mr. Madison wrote to Jefferson on May 11, 1794: "And the tax on carriages
succeeded, in spite of the Constitution, by a majority of twenty, the advocates
for the principle being reinforced by the adversaries to luxuries."
"Some of the motives which they decoyed to their support ought to
premonish them of the danger. By breaking down the barriers of the
Constitution, and giving sanction to the idea of sumptuary regulations, wealth
may find a precarious defence in the shield of justice. If luxury, as such, is
to be taxed, the greatest of all luxuries, says Paine, is a great estate. Even
on the present occasion, it has been found prudent to yield to a tax on
transfers of stock [***250] in the funds and in the banks." 2
Madison's Writings, 14.
But Albert Gallatin in his "Sketch of the Finances of the United
States," published in November, 1796, said: "The most generally
received opinion, however, is, that by direct taxes in the Constitution, those
are meant which are raised on the capital or revenue of the people; by
indirect, such as are raised on their expense. As that opinion is in itself
rational, and conformable to the decision which has taken place on the subject
of the carriage tax, and as it appears important, for the sake of preventing future
controversies, which may be not more fatal to the revenue than to the
tranquility of the Union, that a fixed interpretation should be generally
adopted, it will not be improper to corroborate it by quoting the author from
whom the idea seems to have been borrowed." He then quotes from Smith's
Wealth of Nations, and continues: "The remarkable coincidence of the
clause of the Constitution with this passage in using the word 'capitation' as
a generic [*570] expression, including the different species of
direct taxes, in acceptation of the word peculiar, it is believed, to Dr.
Smith, leaves little doubt that the [***251] framers of the one had
the other in view at the time, and that they, as well as he, by direct taxes,
meant those paid directly from and falling immediately on the revenue; and by
indirect, those which are paid indirectly out of the revenue by falling
immediately upon the expense." 3 Gallatin's Writings, (Adamis's ed.) 74,
75.
The act provided in its first section "that there shall be levied,
collected, and paid upon all carriages for the conveyance of persons, which
shall be kept by or for any person for his or her own use, or to be let out to
hire or for the conveyance of passengers, the several duties and rates
following," and then followed a fixed yearly rate on every coach; chariot;
phaeton and coachee; every four-wheel and every two-wheel top carriage; and
upon every other two-wheel carriage; varying according to the vehicle.
In Hylton v. United States, 3 Dall. 171, decided in March, 1796, this court
held the act to be constitutional, because not laying a direct tax. Chief
Justice Ellsworth and Mr. Justice Cushing took no part in the decision, and Mr.
Justice Wilson gave no reasons.
Mr. Justice Chase said that he was inclined to think, but of this he did not
"give a judicial [***252] opinion," that "the direct
taxes contemplated by the Constitution, are only two, to wit, a capitation, or
poll tax, simply, without regard to property, profession, or any other
circumstance; and a tax on land;" and that he doubted "whether a tax,
by a general assessment of personal property, within the United States, is
included within the term direct tax." But he thought that "an annual
tax on carriages for the conveyance of persons, may be considered as within the
power granted to Congress to lay duties. The term duty, is the most
comprehensive next to the generical term tax; and practically in Great Britain,
(whence we take our general ideas of taxes, duties, imposts, excises, customs,
etc.,) embraces taxes on stamps, tolls for passage, etc., and is not confined
to taxes on importation only. It seems to me, that a tax on expense is an
indirect [*571] tax; and I think, an annual tax on a carriage for
the conveyance of persons, is of that kind; because a carriage is a consumable
commodity; and such annual tax on it, is on the expense of the owner."
Mr. Justice Paterson said that "the Constitution declares, that a
capitation tax is a direct tax; and, both in theory and practice,
[***253] a tax on land is deemed to be a direct tax. . . . It is
not necessary to determine, whether a tax on the product of land be a direct or
indirect tax. Perhaps, the immediate product of land, in its original and crude
state, ought to be considered as the land itself; it makes part of it; or else
the provision made against taxing exports would be easily eluded. Land,
independently of its produce, is of no value. . . . Whether direct taxes, in
the sense of the Constitution, comprehend any other tax than a capitation tax,
and taxes on land, is a questionable point. . . . But as it is not before the
court, it would be improper to give any decisive opinion upon it." And he
concluded: "All taxes on expenses or consumption are indirect taxes.
[**686] A tax on carriages is of this kind, and of course is not a
direct tax." This conclusion he fortified by reading extracts from Adam
Smith on the taxation of consumable commodities.
Mr. Justice Iredell said: "There is no necessity, or propriety, in
determining what is or is not, a direct, or indirect, tax in all cases. Some
difficulties may occur which we do not at present foresee. Perhaps a direct
tax, in the sense of the [***254] Constitution, can mean nothing
but a tax on something inseparably annexed to the soil; something capable of
apportionment under all such circumstances. A land or a poll tax may be
considered of this description. . . . In regard to other articles, there may
possibly be considerable doubt. It is sufficient, on the present occasion, for
the court to be satisfied, that this is not a direct tax contemplated by the
Constitution, in order to affirm the present judgment."
It will be perceived that each of the justices, while suggesting doubt whether
anything but a capitation or a land tax was a direct tax within the meaning of
the Constitution, distinctly avoided expressing an opinion upon that question
or [*572] laying down a comprehensive definition, but confined his
opinion to the case before the court.
The general line of observation was obviously influenced by Mr. Hamilton's
brief for the government, in which he said: "The following are presumed to
be the only direct taxes: Capitation or poll taxes, taxes on lands and
buildings, general assessments, whether on the whole property of individuals,
or on their whole real or personal estate. All else must of necessity be
considered [***255] as indirect taxes." 7 Hamilton's Works,
(Lodge's ed.) 332.
Mr. Hamilton also argued: "If the meaning of the word 'excise' is to be
sought in a British statute, it will be found to include the duty on carriages,
which is there considered as an 'excise.' . . . An argument results from this,
though not perhaps a conclusive one, yet, where so important a distinction in
the Constitution is to be realized, it is fair to seek the meaning of terms in
the statutory language of that country from which our jurisprudence is
derived." Id. 333.
If the question had related to an income tax, the reference would have been
fatal, as such taxes have been always classed by the law of Great Britain as
direct taxes.
The above act was to be enforced for two years, but before it expired was
repealed as was the similar act of May 28, 1796, c. 37, which expired August
31, 1801, 1 Stat. 478, 482.
By the act of July 14, 1798, when a war with France was supposed to be
impending, a direct tax of two millions of dollars was apportioned to the
States respectively, in the manner prescribed, which tax was to be collected by
officers of the United States and assessed upon "dwelling houses, lands, and
slaves," [***256] according to the valuations and enumerations
to be made pursuant to the act of July 9, 1798, entitled "An act to
provide for the valuation of lands and dwelling houses and the enumeration of
slaves within the United States." 1 Stat. 597, c. 75; Id. 580, c. 70.
Under these acts every dwelling house was assessed according to a prescribed
value, and the sum of fifty cents upon every slave enumerated, and the residue
of the sum apportioned was directed to be assessed upon the lands within each
State according to the valuation [*573] made pursuant to the prior
act and at such rate per centum as would be sufficient to produce said
remainder. By the act of August 2, 1813, a direct tax of three millions of
dollars was laid and apportioned to the States respectively, and reference had
to the prior act of July 22, 1813, which provided that whenever a direct tax
should be laid by the authority of the United States the same should be
assessed and laid "on the value of all lands, lots of ground with their
improvements, dwelling houses, and slaves, which several articles subject to
taxation shall be enumerated and valued by the respective assessors at the rate
each of them is worth in money." [***257] 3 Stat. 53, c. 37;
Id. 22, c. 16. The act of January 9, 1815, laid a direct tax of six millions of
dollars, which was apportioned, assessed, and laid as in the prior act on all
lands, lots of grounds with their improvements, dwelling houses, and slaves.
These acts are attributable to the war of 1812.
The act of August 5, 1861, (12 Stat. 292, 294, c. 45,) imposed a tax of twenty
millions of dollars, which was apportioned and to be levied wholly on real
estate, and also levied taxes on incomes whether derived from property or
profession, trade or vocation, (12 Stat. 309,) and this was followed by the
acts of July 1, 1862, (12 Stat. 432, 473, c. 119;) March 3, 1863, (12 Stat.
713, 723, c. 74;) June 30, 1864, (13 Stat. 223, 281, c. 173;) March 3, 1865,
(13 Stat. 469, 479, c. 78;) March 10, 1866, (14 Stat. 4, c. 15;) July 13, 1866,
(14 Stat. 98, 137, c. 184;) March 2, 1867, (14 Stat. 471, 477, c. 169;) and
July 14, 1870, (16 Stat. 256, c. 255). The differences between the latter acts
and that of August 15, 1894, call for no remark in this connection. These acts
grew out of the war of the rebellion, and were, to use the language of Mr.
Justice Miller, "part of the system of taxing [***258]
incomes, earnings, and profits adopted during the late war, and abandoned as
soon after that war was ended as it could be done safely." Railroad
Company v. Collector, 100 U.S. 595, 598.
From the foregoing it is apparent: 1. That the distinction between direct and
indirect taxation was well understood by the framers of the Constitution and
those who adopted it. 2. That under the state systems of taxation all taxes on
[*574] real estate or personal property or the rents or income
thereof were regarded as direct taxes. 3. That the rules of apportionment and
of uniformity were adopted in view of that distinction and those systems. 4.
That whether the tax on carriages was direct [**687] or indirect
was disputed, but the tax was sustained as a tax on the use and an excise. 5.
That the original expectation was that the power of direct taxation would be
exercised only in extraordinary exigencies, and down to August 15, 1894, this
expectation has been realized. The act of that date was passed in a time of
profound peace, and if we assume that no special exigency called for unusual
legislation, and that resort to this mode of taxation is to become an ordinary
and usual means [***259] of supply, that fact furnishes an
additional reason for circumspection and care in disposing of the case.
We proceed then to examine certain decisions of this court under the acts of
1861 and following years, in which it is claimed that this court has heretofore
adjudicated that taxes like those under consideration are not direct taxes and
subject to the rule of apportionment, and that we are bound to accept the
rulings thus asserted to have been made as conclusive in the premises. Is this
contention well founded as respects the question now under examination?
Doubtless the doctrine of stare decisis is a salutary one, and to be adhered to
on all proper occasions, but it only arises in respect of decisions directly
upon the points in issue.
The language of Chief Justice Marshall, in Cohens v. Virginia, 6 Wheat. 264,
399, may profitably again be quoted: "It is a maxim not to be disregarded,
that general expressions, in every opinion, are to be taken in connection with
the case in which those expressions are used. If they go beyond the case, they
may be respected, but ought not to control the judgment in a subsequent suit
when the very point is presented for decision. [***260] The reason of
this maxim is obvious. The question actually before the court is investigated
with care, and considered in its full extent. Other principles which may serve
to illustrate it, are considered in their relation to the case decided, but
their possible bearing on all other cases is seldom completely
investigated."
[*575] So in Carroll v. Lessee of Carroll, 16 How. 275, 286, where
a statute of the State of Maryland came under review, Mr. Justice Curtis said:
"If the construction put by the court of a State upon one of its statutes
was not a matter in judgment, if it might have been decided either way without
affecting any right brought into question, then, according to the principles of
the common law, an opinion on such a question is not a decision. To make it so,
there must have been an application of the judicial mind to the precise
question necessary to be determined to fix the rights of the parties and decide
to whom the property in contestation belongs. And therefore this court, and
other courts organized under the common law, has never held itself bound by any
part of an opinion, in any case, which was not needful to the ascertainment of
the right or title [***261] in question between the parties."
Nor is the language of Mr. Chief Justice Taney inapposite, as expressed in The
Genesee Chief, 12 How. 443, 455, wherein it was held that the lakes and
navigable waters connecting them are within the scope of admiralty and maritime
jurisdiction as known and understood in the United States when the Constitution
was adopted, and the preceding case of The Thomas Jefferson, 10 Wheat. 428, was
overruled. The Chief Justice said: "It was under the influence of these
precedents and this usage, that the case of The Thomas Jefferson, 10 Wheat.
428, was decided in this court; and the jurisdiction of the courts of admiralty
of the United States declared to be limited to the ebb and flow of the tide.
The Steamboat Orleans v. Phoebus, 11 Pet. 175, afterwards followed this case,
merely as a point decided. It is the decision in the case of The Thomas
Jefferson which mainly embarrasses the court in the present inquiry. We are
sensible of the great weight to which it is entitled. But at the same time we
are convinced that, if we follow it, we follow an erroneous decision into which
the court fell, when the great importance of the question as it now presents
itself [***262] could not be foreseen; and the subject did not
therefore receive that deliberate consideration which at this time would have
been given to it by the eminent men who presided here when that case was
decided. [*576] For the decision was made in 1825, when the
commerce on the rivers of the West and on the Lakes was in its infancy, and of
little importance, and but little regarded compared with that of the present
day. Moreover, the nature of the questions concerning the extent of the
admiralty jurisdiction, which have arisen in this court, were not calculated to
call its attention particularly to the one we are now considering."
Manifestly, as this court is clothed with the power, and entrusted with the
duty, to maintain the fundamental law of the Constitution, the discharge of
that duty requires it not to extend any decision upon a constitutional question
if it is convinced that error in principle might supervene.
Let us examine the cases referred to in the light of these observations.
In Pacific Insurance Co. v. Soule, 7 Wall. 433, the validity of a tax which was
described as "upon the business of an insurance company" was
sustained on the ground that it was "a duty or excise,"
[***263] and came within the decision in Hylton's case. The
arguments for the insurance company were elaborate and took a wide range, but
the decision rested on narrow ground, and turned on the distinction between an
excise duty and a tax strictly so termed, regarding the former a charge for a
privilege, or on the transaction of business, without any necessary reference
to the amount of property belonging to those on whom the charge might fall,
although it might be increased or diminished by the extent to which the
privilege was exercised or [**688] the business done. This was in
accordance with Society for Savings v. Coite, 6 Wall. 594; Provident
Institution v. Massachusetts, 6 Wall. 611; and Hamilton Company v.
Massachusetts, 6 Wall. 632; in which cases there was a difference of opinion on
the question whether the tax under consideration was a tax on the property and
not upon the franchise or privilege. And see Van Allen v. The Assessors, 3
Wall. 573; Home Insurance Co. v. New York, 134 U.S. 594; Pullman Co. v.
Pennsylvania, 141 U.S. 18.
In Veazie Bank v. Fenno, 8 Wall. 533, 544, 546, a tax was laid on the
circulation of state banks or national banks paying out the notes of
individuals [***264] or state banks, and it was [*577]
held that it might well be classed under the head of duties, and as falling
within the same category as Soule's case, 8 Wall. 547. It was declared to be of
the same nature as excise taxation on freight receipts, bills of lading, and
passenger tickets issued by a railroad company. Referring to the discussions in
the convention which framed the Constitution, Mr. Chief Justice Chase observed
that what was said there "doubtless shows uncertainty as to the true
meaning of the term direct tax; but it indicates also an understanding that
direct taxes were such as may be levied by capitation, and on lands and
appurtenances; or, perhaps, by valuation and assessment of personal property
upon general lists. For these were the subjects from which the States at that
time usually raised their principal supplies." And in respect of the
opinions in Hylton's case, the Chief Justice said: "It may further be
taken as established upon the testimony of Paterson, that the words direct
taxes, as used in the Constitution, comprehended only capitation taxes and
taxes on land, and perhaps taxes on personal property by general valuation and
assessment of the [***265] various descriptions possessed within
the several States."
In National Bank v. United States, 101 U.S. 1, involving the constitutionality
of § 3413 of the Revised Statutes, enacting that "every national banking
association, state bank, or banker, or association, shall pay a tax of ten per
centum on the amount of notes of any town, city, or municipal corporation, paid
out by them," Veazie Bank v. Fenno was cited with approval to the point
that Congress, having undertaken to provide a currency for the whole country,
might, to secure the benefit of it to the people, restrain, by suitable
enactments, the circulation as money of any notes not issued under its
authority; and Mr. Chief Justice Waite, speaking for the court, said: "The
tax thus laid is not on the obligation, but on its use in a particular
way."
Scholey v. Rew, 23 Wall. 331, was the case of a succession tax which the court
held to be "plainly an excise tax or duty" upon the devolution of the
estate or the right to become beneficially entitled to the same, or the income
thereof, in [*578] possession or expectancy." It was like the
succession tax of a State, held constitutional in Mager v. Grima, 8 How. 490;
and the [***266] distinction between the power of a State and the
power of the United States to regulate the succession of property was not
referred to, and does not appear to have been in the mind of the court. The
opinion stated that the act of Parliament, from which the particular provision
under consideration was borrowed, had received substantially the same
construction, and cases under that act hold that a succession duty is not a tax
upon income or upon property, but on the actual benefit derived by the
individual, determined as prescribed. In re Elwes, 3 H. & N. 719;
Attorney-General v. Sefton, 2 H. & C. 362; S.C. (H.L.) 3 H. & C. 1023;
11 H.L. Cas. 257.
In Railroad Company v. Collector, 100 U.S. 595, 596, the validity of a tax
collected of a corporation upon the interest paid by it upon its bonds was held
to be "essentially an excise on the business of the class of corporations
mentioned in the statute." And Mr. Justice Miller, in delivering the opinion,
said: "As the sum involved in this suit is small, and the law under which
the tax in question was collected has long since been repealed, the case is of
little consequence as regards any principle involved in it as a rule of future
action." [***267]
All these cases are distinguishable from that in hand, and this brings us to
consider that of Springer v. United States, 102 U.S. 586, 602, chiefly relied
on and urged upon us as decisive.
That was an action of ejectment brought on a tax deed issued to the United
States on sale of defendant's real estate for income taxes. The defendant
contended that the deed was void because the tax was a direct tax, not levied
in accordance with the Constitution. Unless the tax were wholly invalid, the
defence failed.
The statement of the case in the report shows that Springer returned a certain
amount as his net income for the particular year, but does not give the details
of what his income, gains, and profits consisted in.
The original record discloses that the income was not [*579]
derived in any degree from real estate but was in part professional as
attorney-at-law and the rest interest on United States bonds. It would seem
probable that the court did not feel called upon to advert to the distinction
between the latter and the former source of income, as the validity of the tax
as to either would sustain the action.
The opinion thus concludes: "Our conclusions are, that direct
[***268] taxes, within the meaning of the Constitution, are only
capitation taxes, as expressed in that instrument, and taxes on real estate;
and that the tax of which the plaintiff in error complains is within the
category of an excise or duty."
While this language is broad enough to cover the interest as well as the
professional earnings, the case would have been more significant as a precedent
if the distinction had [**689] been brought out in the report and
commented on in arriving at judgment, for a tax on professional receipts might
be treated as an excise or duty, and therefore indirect, when a tax on the
income of personalty might be held to be direct.
Be this as it may, it is conceded in all these cases, from that of Hylton to
that of Springer, that taxes on land are direct taxes, and in none of them is
it determined that taxes on rents or income derived from land are not taxes on
land.
We admit that it may not unreasonably be said that logically, if taxes on the
rents, issues and profits of real estate are equivalent to taxes on real
estate, and are therefore direct taxes, taxes on the income of personal
property as such are equivalent to taxes on such property, and therefore
[***269] direct taxes. But we are considering the rule stare
decisis, and we must decline to hold ourselves bound to extend the scope of decisions
-- none of which discussed the question whether a tax on the income from
personalty is equivalent to a tax on that personalty, but all of which held
real estate liable to direct taxation only -- so as to sustain a tax on the
income of realty on the ground of being an excise or duty.
As no capitation, or other direct, tax was to be laid otherwise than in
proportion to the population, some other direct tax than a capitation tax (and
it might well enough be argued some other tax of the same kind as a capitation tax)
must be [*580] referred to, and it has always been considered that
a tax upon real estate eo nomine or upon its owners in respect thereof is a
direct tax within the meaning of the Constitution. But is there any distinction
between the real estate itself or its owners in respect of it and the rents or
income of the real estate coming to the owners as the natural and ordinary
incident of their ownership?
If the Constitution had provided that Congress should not levy and tax upon the
real estate of any citizen of any [***270] State, could it be
contended that Congress could put an annual tax for five or any other number of
years upon the rent or income of the real estate? And if, as the Constitution
now reads, no unapportioned tax can be imposed upon real estate, and Congress
without apportionment nevertheless impose taxes upon such real estate under the
guise of an annual tax upon its rents or income?
As according to the feudal law, the whole beneficial interest in the land
consisted in the right to take the rents and profits, the general rule has
always been, in the language of Coke, that "if a man seized of land in fee
by his deed granteth to another the profits of those lands, to have and to hold
to him and his heirs, and maketh livery secundum formam chartae, the whole land
itself doth pass. For what is the land but the profits thereof?" Co. Lit.
45. And that a devise of the rents and profits or of the income of lands passes
the land itself both at law and in equity. 1 Jarm. on Wills, (5th ed.,) *798
and cases cited.
The requirement of the Constitution is that no direct tax shall be laid
otherwise than by apportionment -- the prohibition is not against direct taxes
on land, from which the implication [***271] is sought to be drawn
that indirect taxes on land would be constitutional, but it is against all
direct taxes -- and it is admitted that a tax on real estate is a direct tax.
Unless, therefore, a tax upon rents or income issuing out of lands is
intrinsically so different from a tax on the land itself that it belongs to a
wholly different class of taxes, such taxes must be regarded as falling within
the same category as a tax on real estate eo nomine. The name of the tax is
unimportant. [*581] The real question is, is there any basis upon which
to rest the contention that real estate belongs to one of the two great classes
of taxes, and the rent or income which is the incident of its ownership belongs
to the other? We are unable to perceive any ground for the alleged distinction.
An annual tax upon the annual value or annual user of real estate appears to us
the same in substance as an annual tax on the real estate, which would be paid
out of the rent or income. This law taxes the income received from land and the
growth or produce of the land. Mr. Justice Paterson observed in Hylton's case,
"land, independently of its produce, is of no value;" and certainly
had no thought [***272] that direct taxes were confined to
unproductive land.
If it be true that by varying the form the substance may be changed, it is not
easy to see that anything would remain of the limitations of the Constitution,
or of the rule of taxation and representation, so carefully recognized and
guarded in favor of the citizens of each State. But constitutional provisions
cannot be thus evaded. It is the substance and not the form which controls, as
has indeed been established by repeated decisions of this court. Thus in Brown
v. Maryland, 12 Wheat. 419, 444, it was held that the tax on the occupation of
an importer was the same as a tax on imports and therefore void. And Chief
Justice Marshall said: "It is impossible to conceal from ourselves, that
this is varying the form, without varying the substance. It is treating a
prohibition which is general, as if it were confined to a particular mode of
doing the forbidden thing. All must perceive, that a tax on the sale of an
article, imported only for sale, is a tax on the article itself."
In Weston v. Charleston, 2 Pet. 449, it was held that a tax on the income of
United States securities was a tax on the securities themselves, and equally
[***273] inadmissible. The ordinance of the city of Charleston
involved in that case was exceedingly obscure; but the opinions of Mr. Justice
Thompson and [**690] Mr. Justice Johnson, who dissented, make it
clear that the levy was upon the interest of the bonds and not upon the bonds,
and they held that it was an income tax, and as [*582] such
sustainable; but the majority of the court, Chief Justice Marshall delivering
the opinion, overruled that contention.
So in Dobbins v. Commissioners, 16 Pet. 435, it was decided that the income
from an official position could not be taxed if the office itself was exempt.
In Almy v. California, 24 How. 169, it was held that a duty on a bill of lading
was the same thing as a duty on the article which it represented; in Railroad
Co. v. Jackson, 7 Wall. 262, that a tax upon the interest payable on bonds was
a tax not upon the debtor, but upon the security; and in Cook v. Pennsylvania,
97 U.S. 566, that a tax upon the amount of sales of goods made by an auctioneer
was a tax upon the goods sold.
In Philadelphia Steamship Co. v. Pennsylvania, 122 U.S. 326, and Leloup v.
Mobile, 127 U.S. 640, it was held that a tax on income received from interstate
[***274] commerce was a tax upon the commerce itself, and therefore
unauthorized. And so, although it is thoroughly settled that where by way of
duties laid on the transportation of the subjects of interstate commerce, and
on the receipts derived therefrom, or on the occupation or business of carrying
it on, a tax is levied by a State on interstate commerce, such taxation amounts
to a regulation of such commerce, and cannot be sustained, yet the property in
a State belonging to a corporation, whether foreign or domestic, engaged in
foreign or domestic commerce, may be taxed, and when the tax is substantially a
mere tax on property and not one imposed on the privilege of doing interstate
commerce, the exaction may be sustained. "The substance, and not the shadow,
determines the validity of the exercise of the power." Postal Telegraph
Co. v. Adams, 155 U.S. 688, 698.
Nothing can be clearer than that what the Constitution intended to guard
against was the exercise by the general government of the power of directly
taxing persons and property within any State through a majority made up from
the other States. It is true that the effect of requiring direct taxes to be
apportioned [***275] among the States in proportion to their
population is necessarily that the amount of taxes on the individual
[*583] taxpayer in a State having the taxable subject-matter to a
larger extent in proportion to its population than another State has, would be
less than in such other State, but this inequality must be held to have been
contemplated, and was manifestly designed to operate to restrain the exercise
of the power of direct taxation to extraordinary emergencies, and to prevent an
attack upon accumulated property by mere force of numbers.
It is not doubted that property owners ought to contribute in just measure to
the expenses of the government. As to the States and their municipalities, this
is reached largely through the imposition of direct taxes. As to the Federal
government, it is attained in part through excises and indirect taxes upon
luxuries and consumption generally, to which direct taxation may be added to
the extent the rule of apportionment allows. And through one mode or the other,
the entire wealth of the country, real and personal, may be made, as it should be,
to contribute to the common defence and general welfare.
But the acceptance of the rule of [***276] apportionment was one of
the compromises which made the adoption of the Constitution possible, and
secured the creation of that dual form of government, so elastic and so strong,
which has thus far survived in unabated vigor. If, by calling a tax indirect
when it is essentially direct, the rule of protection could be frittered away,
one of the great landmarks defining the boundary between the Nation and the
States of which it is composed, would have disappeared, and with it one of the
bulwarks of private rights and private property.
We are of opinion that the law in question, so far as it levies a tax on the
rents or income of real estate, is in violation of the Constitution, and is
invalid.
Another question is directly presented by the record as to the validity of the
tax levied by the act upon the income derived from municipal bonds. The
averment in the bill is that the defendant company owns two millions of the
municipal bonds of the city of New York, from which it derives an annual income
of $ 60,000, and that the directors of the company intend to return and pay the
taxes on the income so derived.
The Constitution contemplates the independent exercise by [*584]
the [***277] Nation and the State, severally, of their
constitutional powers.
As the States cannot tax the powers, the operations, or the property of the
United States, nor the means which they employ to carry their powers into execution,
so it has been held that the United States have no power under the Constitution
to tax either the instrumentalities or the property of a State.
A municipal corporation is the representative of the State and one of the
instrumentalities of the state government. It was long ago determined that the
property and revenues of municipal corporations are not subjects of Federal
taxation. Collector v. Day, 11 Wall. 113, 124; United States v. Railroad
Company, 17 Wall. 322, 332. In Collector v. Day, it was adjudged that Congress
had no power, even by an act taxing all incomes, to levy a tax upon the
salaries of judicial officers of a State, for reasons similar to those on which
it had been held in Dobbins v. Commissioners, 16 Pet. 435, that a State could not
tax the salaries [**691] of officers of the United States. Mr.
Justice Nelson, in delivering judgment, said: "The general government, and
the States, although both exist within the same territorial limits,
[***278] are separate and distinct sovereignties, acting separately
and independently of each other, within their respective spheres. The former in
its appropriate sphere is supreme; but the States within the limits of their
powers not granted, or, in the language of the tenth amendment, 'reserved,' are
as independent of the general government as that government within its sphere
is independent of the States."
This is quoted in Van Brocklin v. Tennessee, 117 U.S. 151, 178, and the opinion
continues: "Applying the same principles, this court, in United States v.
Railroad Company, 17 Wall. 322, held that a municipal corporation within a
State could not be taxed by the United States on the dividends or interest of
stock or bonds held by it in a railroad or canal company, because the municipal
corporation was a representative of the State, created by the State to exercise
a limited portion of its powers of government, and therefore its revenues, like
those of the State itself, were not taxable by the United States. The revenues
thus adjudged to be exempt from Federal taxation [*585] were not
themselves appropriated to any specific public use, nor derived from property
held by the State [***279] or by the municipal corporation for any
specific public use, but were part of the general income of that corporation,
held for the public use in no other sense than all property and income,
belonging to it in its municipal character, must be so held. The reasons for
exempting all the property and income of a State, or of a municipal
corporation, which is a political division of the State, from Federal taxation,
equally require the exemption of all the property and income of the national
government from state taxation."
In Mercantile Bank v. New York, 121 U.S. 138, 162, this court said: "Bonds
issued by the State of New York, or under its authority by its public municipal
bodies, are means for carrying on the work of the government, and are not
taxable even by the United States, and it is not a part of the policy of the
government which issues them to subject them to taxation for its own
purposes."
The question in Bonaparte v. Tax Court, 104 U.S. 592, was whether the
registered public debt of one State, exempt from taxation by that State or
actually taxed there, was taxable by another State when owned by a citizen of
the latter, and it was held that there was no provision of the
[***280] Constitution of the United States which prohibited such
taxation. The States had not convenanted that this could not be done, whereas,
under the fundamental law, as to the power to borrow money, neither the United
States on the one hand, nor the States on the other, can interfere with that
power as possessed by each and an essential element of the sovereignty of each.
The law under consideration provides "that nothing herein contained shall
apply to States, counties or municipalities." It is contended that
although the property or revenues of the States or their instrumentalities
cannot be taxed, nevertheless the income derived from state, county, and
municipal securities can be taxed. But we think the same want of power to tax
the property or revenues of the States or their instrumentalities exists in
relation to a tax on the income from their securities, and for the same reason,
and that reason [*586] is given by Chief Justice Marshall in Weston
v. Charleston, 2 Pet. 449, 468, where he said: "The right to tax the
contract to any extent, when made, must operate upon the power to borrow before
it is exercised, and have a sensible influence on the contract. The [***281]
extent of this influence, depends on the will of a distinct government. To any
extent, however inconsiderable, it is a burthen on the operations of
government. It may be carried to an extent which shall arrest them entirely. .
. . The tax on government stock is thought by this court to be a tax on the
contract, a tax on the power to borrow money on the credit of the United
States, and consequently to be repugnant to the Constitution." Applying
this language to these municipal securities, it is obvious that taxation on the
interest therefrom would operate on the power to borrow before it is exercised,
and would have a sensible influence on the contract, and that the tax in
question is a tax on the power of the States and their instrumentalities to
borrow money, and consequently repugnant to the Constitution.
Upon each of the other questions argued at the bar, to wit, 1, Whether the void
provisions as to rents and income from real estate invalidated the whole act?
2, Whether as to the income from personal property as such, the act is
unconstitutional as laying direct taxes? 3, Whether any part of the tax, if not
considered as a direct tax, is invalid for want of uniformity on
[***282] either of the grounds suggested? -- the justices who heard
the argument are equally divided, and, therefore, no opinion is expressed.
The result is that the decree of the Circuit Court is reversed and the cause
remanded with directions to enter a decree in favor of the complainant in
respect only of the voluntary payment of the tax on the rents and income of the
real estate of the defendant company, and of that which it holds in trust, and
on the income from the municipal bonds owned or so held by it.
MR. JUSTICE FIELD.
I also desire to place my opinion on record upon some of the important
questions discussed in relation to the direct and indirect taxes proposed by
the income tax law of 1894.
[*587] Several suits have been instituted in state
[**692] and Federal courts, both at law and in equity, to test the
validity of the provisions of the law, the determination of which will
necessitate careful and extended consideration.
The subject of taxation in the new government which was to be established
created great interest in the convention which framed the Constitution, and was
the cause of much difference of opinion among its members and earnest
contention between [***283] the States. The great source of
weakness of the confederation was its inability to levy taxes of any kind for
the support of its government. To raise revenue it was obliged to make
requisitions upon the States, which were respected or disregarded at their
pleasure. Great embarrassments followed the consequent inability to obtain the
necessary funds to carry on the government. One of the principal objects of the
proposed new government was to obviate this defect of the confederacy by
conferring authority upon the new government by which taxes could be directly
laid whenever desired. Great difficulty in accomplishing this object was found
to exist. The States bordering on the ocean were unwilling to give up their
right to lay duties upon imports which were their chief source of revenue. The
other States, on the other hand, were unwilling to make any agreement for the
levying of taxes directly upon real and personal property, the smaller States
fearing that they would be overborne by unequal burdens forced upon them by the
action of the larger States. In this condition of things great embarrassment
was felt by the members of the convention. It was feared at times that the
effort [***284] to form a new government would fail. But happily a
compromise was effected by an agreement that direct taxes should be laid by
Congress by apportioning them among the States according to their
representation. In return for this concession by some of the States, the other
States bordering on navigable waters consented to relinquish to the new
government the control of duties, imposts, and excises, and the regulation of
commerce, with the condition that the duties, imposts, and excises should be
uniform throughout the United States. So that, on the one [*588]
hand, anything like oppression or undue advantage of any one State over the
others would be prevented by the apportionment of the direct taxes among the
States according to their representation, and, on the other hand, anything like
oppression or hardship in the levying of duties, imposts, and excises would be
avoided by the provision that they should be uniform throughout the United
States. This compromise was essential to the continued union and harmony of the
States. It protected every State from being controlled in its taxation by the
superior numbers of one or more other States.
The Constitution accordingly, [***285] when completed, divided the
taxes which might be levied under the authority of Congress into those which
were direct and those which were indirect. Direct taxes, in a general and large
sense, may be described as taxes derived immediately from the person, or from
real or personal property, without any recourse therefrom to other sources for
reimbursement. In a more restricted sense, they have sometimes been confined to
taxes on real property, including the rents and income derived therefrom. Such
taxes are conceded to be direct taxes, however taxes on other property are
designated, and they are to be apportioned among the States of the Union
according to their respective numbers. The second section of article I of the
Constitution declares that representatives and direct taxes shall be thus
apportioned. It had been a favorite doctrine in England and in the colonies,
before the adoption of the Constitution, that taxation and representation
should go together. The Constitution prescribes such apportionment among the
several States according to their respective numbers, to be determined by
adding to the whole number of free persons, including those bound to service
for a term of years, [***286] and excluding Indians not taxed,
three-fifths of all other persons.
Some decisions of this court have qualified or thrown doubts upon the exact
meaning of the words "direct taxes." Thus in Springer v. United
States, 102 U.S. 586, it was held that a tax upon gains, profits, and income
was an excise or duty and not a direct tax within the meaning of the Constitution,
and [*589] that its imposition was not therefore unconstitutional.
And in Pacific Insurance Co. v. Soule, 7 Wall. 433, it was held that an income
tax or duty upon the amounts insured, renewed or continued by insurance
companies, upon the gross amounts of premiums received by them and upon
assessments made by them, and upon dividends and undistributed sums, was not a
direct tax but a duty or excise.
In the discussions on the subject of direct taxes in the British Parliament an
income tax has been generally designated as a direct tax, differing in that
respect from the decision of this court in Springer v. United States. But
whether the latter can be accepted as correct or otherwise, it does not affect
the tax upon real property and its rents and income as a direct tax. Such a tax
is by universal consent recognized [***287] to be a direct tax.
As stated, the rents and income of real property are included in the
designation of direct taxes as part of the real property. Such has been the law
in England for centuries, and in this country from the early settlement of the
colonies; and it is strange that any member of the legal profession should, at
this day, question a doctrine which has always been thus accepted by common-law
lawyers. It is so declared in approved treatises upon real property and in
accepted authorities on particular branches of real estate law, and has been so
announced in decisions in the English courts and our own courts without number.
Thus, in Washburn on Real Property, it is said that "a devise of the rents
[**693] and profits of land, or the income of land, is equivalent
to a devise of the land itself, and will be for life or in fee, according to
the limitation expressed in the devise." Vol. 2, p. 695, § 30.
In Jarman on Wills, Vol. 1, page 740, it is laid down that "a devise of
the rents and profits or of the income of land passes the land itself both at
law and in equity; a rule, it is said, founded on the feudal law, according to
which the whole beneficial interest [***288] in the land consisted
in the right to take the rents and profits. And since the act 1 Vict. c. 26,
such a devise carries the fee simple; but before that act it carried no more
than an estate for life unless words of inheritance were [*590]
added." Mr. Jarman cites numerous authorities in support of his statement.
South v. Alleine, 1 Salk. 228; Doe d. Goldin v. Lakeman, 2 B. & Ad. 30, 42;
Johnson v. Arnold, 1 Ves. Sen. 171; Baines v. Dixon, 1 Ves. Sen. 42; Mannox v.
Greener, L.R. 14 Eq. 456; Blann v. Bell, 2 De G., M. & G. 781; Plenty v.
West, 6 C.B. 201.
Coke upon Littleton says: "If a man seised of lands in fee by his deed
granteth to another the profit of those lands, to have and to hold to him and
his heires, and maketh livery secundum formam chartae, the whole land itselfe,
doth passe; for what is the land but the profits thereof?" Lib. 1, cap. 1,
§ 1, p. 4b.
In Doe d. Goldin v. Lakeman, Lord Tenterden, Chief Justice of the Court of
King's Bench, to the same effect said: "It is an established rule that a
devise of the rents and profits is a devise of the land." And in Johnson
v. Arnold, Lord Chancellor Hardwicke reiterated the doctrine that a
"devise of the profits [***289] of lands is a devise of the
lands themselves."
The same rule is announced in this country; the Court of Errors of New York in
Paterson v. Ellis, 11 Wend. 259, 298, holding that the "devise of the
interest or of the rents and profits is a devise of the thing itself, out of
which that interest or those rents and profits may issue;" and the Supreme
Court of Massachusetts, in Reed v. Reed, 9 Mass. 372, 374, that "a devise
of the income of lands is the same in its effect as a devise of the
lands." The same view of the law was expressed in Anderson v. Greble, 1
Ashmead (Penn.) 136, 138, King, the president of the court, stating: "I
take it to be a well-settled rule of law, that by a devise of the rent,
profits, and income of land, the land itself passes." Similar
adjudications might be repeated almost indefinitely. One may have the reports
of the English courts examined for several centuries without finding a single
decision or even a dictum of their judges in conflict with them. And what
answer do we receive to these adjudications? Those rejecting them furnish no
proof that the framers of the Constitution did not follow them, as the great
body of the people of the country then did. [***290] An incident
which occurred in this court and room twenty [*591] years ago, may
have become a precedent. To a powerful argument then being made by a distinguished
counsel, on a public question, one of the judges exclaimed that there was a
conclusive answer to his position and that was that the court was of a
different opinion. Those who decline to recognize the adjudications cited may
likewise consider that they have a conclusive answer to them in the fact that
they also are of a different opinion. I do not think so. The law as expounded
for centuries cannot be set aside or disregarded because some of the judges are
now of a different opinion from those who, a century ago, followed it in
framing our Constitution.
Hamilton, speaking on the subject, asks: "What, in fact, is property but a
fiction, without the beneficial use of it?" And adds: "In many cases,
indeed, the income or annuity is the property itself." 3 Hamilton's Works,
Putnam's ed. 34.
It must be conceded that whatever affects any element that gives an article its
value, in the eye of the law affects the article itself.
In Brown v. Maryland, 12 Wheat. 419, 444, it was held that a tax on the occupation
[***291] of an importer is the same as a tax on his imports, and as
such was invalid. It was contended that the State might tax occupations and
that this was nothing more, but the court said, by Chief Justice Marshall (p.
444): "It is impossible to conceal from ourselves, that this is varying
the form without varying the substance. It is treating a prohibition, which is
general, as if it were confined to a particular mode of doing the forbidden
thing. All must perceive, that a tax on the sale of an article, imported only
for sale, is a tax on the article itself."
In Weston v. Charleston, 2 Pet. 449, it was held that a tax upon stock issued
for loans to the United States was a tax upon the loans themselves and equally
invalid. In Dobbins v. Commissioners, 16 Pet. 435, it was held that the salary
of an officer of the United States could not be taxed, if the office was itself
exempt. In Almy v. California, 24 How. 169, it was held that a duty on a bill
of lading was the same thing as a duty on the article transported. In Cook v.
Pennsylvania, 97 U.S. 566, it was held that a tax upon the amount
[*592] of sales of goods made by an auctioneer was a tax upon the
goods sold. In Philadelphia [***292] & Southern Steamship Co.
v. Pennsylvania, 122 U.S. 326, and Leloup v. Mobile, 127 U.S. 640, 648, it was
held that a tax upon the income received from interstate commerce was a tax
upon the commerce itself, and equally unauthorized. The same doctrine was held
in People v. Commissioners of Taxes, 90 N.Y. 63; State Freight Tax, 15 Wall.
232, 274; Welton v. Missouri, 91 U.S. 275, 278, and in Fargo v. Michigan, 121
U.S. 230.
The law, so far as it imposes a tax upon land by taxation of the rents and
income [**694] thereof, must therefore fail, as it does not follow
the rule of apportionment. The Constitution is imperative in its directions on
this subject, and admits of no departure from them.
But the law is not invalid merely in its disregard of the rule of apportionment
of the direct tax levied. There is another and an equally cogent objection to
it. In taxing incomes other than rents and profits of real estate it disregards
the rule of uniformity which is prescribed in such cases by the Constitution.
The eighth section of the First article of the Constitution declares that
"the Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts,
and excises, to pay the debts [***293] and provide for the common
defence and general welfare of the United States; but all duties, imposts, and
excises shall be uniform throughout the United States." Excises are a
species of tax consisting generally of duties laid upon the manufacture, sale,
or consumption of commodities within the country, or upon certain callings or
occupations, often taking the form of exactions for licenses to pursue them.
The taxes created by the law under consideration as applied to savings banks,
insurance companies, whether of fire, life, or marine, to building or other
associations, or to the conduct of any other kind of business, are excise
taxes, and fall within the requirement, so far as they are laid by Congress,
that they must be uniform throughout the United States.
The uniformity thus requied is the uniformity throughout the United States of
the duty, impost, and excise levied. That is, the tax levied cannot be one sum
upon an article at one [*593] place and a different sum upon the
same article at another place. The duty received must be the same at all places
throughout the United States, proportioned to the quantity of the article
disposed of or the extent of the business done. [***294] If, for
instance, one kind of wine or grain or produce has a certain duty laid upon it
proportioned to its quantity in New York, it must have a like duty proportioned
to its quantity when imported at Charleston or San Francisco, or if a tax be
laid upon a certain kind of business proportioned to its extent at one place,
it must be a like tax on the same kind of business proportioned to its extent
at another place. In that sense the duty must be uniform throughout the United
States.
It is contended by the government that the Constitution only requires an
uniformity geographical in its character. That position would be satisfied if
the same duty were laid in all the States, however variant it might be in
different places of the same State. But it could not be sustained in the latter
case without defeating the equality, which is an essential element of the
uniformity required, so far as the same is practicable.
In United States v. Singer, 15 Wall. 111, 121, a tax was imposed upon a
distiller, in the nature of an excise, and the question arose whether in its
imposition upon different distillers the uniformity of the tax was preserved,
and the court said: "The law is not in our [***295] judgment
subject to any constitutional objection. The tax imposed upon the distiller is
in the nature of an excise, and the only limitation upon the power of Congress
in the imposition of taxes of this character is that they shall be 'uniform
throughout the United States.' The tax here is uniform in its operation; that
is, it is assessed equally upon all manufacturers of spirits wherever they are.
The law does not establish one rule for one distiller and a different rule for
another, but the same rule for all alike."
In the Head Money Cases, 112 U.S. 580, 594, a tax was imposed upon the owners
of steam vessels for each passenger landed at New York from a foreign port, and
it was objected that the tax was not levied by any rule of uniformity, but the
court, by Justice Miller, replied: "The tax is uniform when
[*594] it operates with the same force and effect in every place
where the subject of it is found. The tax in this case, which, as far as it can
be called a tax, is an excise duty on the business of bringing passengers from
foreign countries into this, by ocean navigation, is uniform and operates
precisely alike in every port of the United States where such
[***296] passengers can be landed." In the decision in that
case, in the Circuit Court, 18 Fed. Rep. 135, 139, Mr. Justice Blatchford, in
addition to pointing out that "the act was not passed in the exercise of
the power of laying taxes," but was a regulation of commerce, used the
following language: "Aside from this, the tax applies uniformly to all
steam and sail vessels coming to all ports in the United States, from all
foreign ports, with all alien passengers.The tax being a license tax on the
business, the rule of uniformity is sufficiently observed if the tax extends to
all persons of the class selected by Congress; that is, to all owners of such
vessels. Congress has the exclusive power of selecting the class. It has
regulated that particular branch of commerce which concerns the bringing of
alien passengers," and that taxes shall be levied upon such property as
shall be prescribed by law. The object of this provision was to prevent unjust
discriminations. It prevents property from being classified and taxed as
classed, by different rules. All kinds of property must be taxed uniformly, or
be entirely exempt. The uniformity must be coextensive with the territory to
which the tax [***297] applies.
Mr. Justice Miller, in his lectures on the Constitution, (N.Y. 1891) pp. 240,
241, said of taxes levied by Congress: "The tax must be uniform on the
particular article; and it is uniform, within the meaning of the constitutional
requirement, if it is made to bear the same percentage over all the United
States. That is manifestly the meaning of this word, as used in this clause.
The framers [**695] of the Constitution could not have meant to say
that the government, in raising its revenues, should not be allowed to
discriminate between the articles which it should tax." In discussing
generally the requirement of uniformity found in state constitutions, he said:
"The difficulties in the way of this construction have, however, been very
largely obviated by the meaning of the word [*595] 'uniform,' which
has been adopted, holding that the uniformity must refer to articles of the
same class. That is, different articles may be taxed at different amounts,
provided the rate is uniform on the same class everywhere, with all people, and
at all times."
One of the learned counsel puts it very clearly when he says that the correct
meaning of the provisions requiring duties [***298] imposts, and
excises to be "uniform throughout the United States" is, that the law
imposing them should "have an equal and uniform application in every part
of the Union."
If there were any doubt as to the intention of the States to make the grant of
the right to impose indirect taxes subject to the condition that such taxes
shall be in all respects uniform and impartial, that doubt, as said by counsel,
should be resolved in the interest of justice, in favor of the taxpayer.
Exemptions from the operation of a tax always create inequalities. Those not
exempted must, in the end, bear an additional burden or pay more than their
share. A law containing arbitrary exemptions can in no just sense be termed
uniform. In my judgment, Congress has rightfully no power, at the expense of
others, owning property of a like character, to sustain private trading
corporations, such as building and loan associations, savings banks, and mutual
life, fire, marine, and accident insurance companies, formed under the laws of
the various States, which advance no national purpose or public interest and
exist solely for the pecuniary profit of their members.
Where property is exempt from taxation, the [***299] exemption, as
has been justly stated, must be supported by some consideration that the
public, and not private, interests will be advanced by it. Private corporations
and private enterprises cannot be aided under the pretence that it is the
exercise of the discretion of the legislature to exempt them. Loan Association
v. Topeka, 20 Wall. 655; Parkersburg v. Brown, 106 U.S. 487; Barbour v.
Louisville Board of Trade, 82 Kentucky, 645, 654, 655; Lexington v. McQuillan's
Heirs, 9 Dana, 513, 516, 517; and Sutton's Heirs v. Louisville, 5 Dana, 28, 31.
Cooley, in his treatise on Taxation, (2d ed. 215,) justly [*596]
observes that: "It is difficult to conceive of a justifiable exemption law
which should select single individuals or corporations, or single articles of
property, and, taking them out of the class to which they belong, make them the
subject of capricious legislative favor. Such favoritism could make no pretence
to equality; it would lack the semblance of legitimate tax legislation."
The income tax law under consideration is marked by discriminating features
which affect the whole law.It discriminates between those who receive an income
of four thousand dollars and [***300] those who do not. It thus
vitiates, in my judgment, by this arbitrary discrimination, the whole
legislation. Hamilton says in one of his papers, (the Continentalist,)
"the genius of liberty reprobates everything arbitrary or discretionary in
taxation. It exacts that every man, by a definite and general rule, should know
what proportion of his property the State demands; whatever liberty we may
boast of in theory, it cannot exist in fact while [arbitrary] assessments
continue." 1 Hamilton's Works, ed. 1885, 270. The legislation, in the
discrimination it makes, is class legislation. Whenever a distinction is made
in the burdens a law imposes or in the benefits it confers on any citizens by
reason of their birth, or wealth, or religion, it is class legislation, and
leads inevitably to oppression and abuses, and to general unrest and
disturbance in society. It was hoped and believed that the great amendments to
the Constitution which followed the late civil war had rendered such
legislation impossible for all future time. But the objectionable legislation
reappears in the act under consideration.It is the same in essential character
as that of the English income statute of 1691, [***301] which taxed
Protestants at a certain rate, Catholics, as a class, at double the rate of
Protestants, and Jews at another and separate rate. Under wise and
constitutional legislation every citizen should contribute his proportion,
however small the sum, to the support of the government, and it is no kindness
to urge any of our citizens to escape from that obligation. If he contributes
the smallest mite of his earnings to that purpose he will have a greater regard
for the government and more self-respect [*597] for himself feeling
that though he is poor in fact, he is not a pauper of his government. And it is
to be hoped that, whatever woes and embarrassments may betide our people, they
may never lose their manliness and self-respect. Those qualities preserved,
they will ultimately triumph over all reverses of fortune.
There is nothing in the nature of the corporations or associations exempted in
the present act, or in their method of doing business, which can be claimed to
be of a public or benevolent nature. They differ in no essential characteristic
in their business from "all other corporations, companies, or associations
doing business for profit in the United [***302] States." Act
of August 15, 1894, c. 349, § 32.
A few words as to some of them, the extent of their capital and business, and
of the exceptions made to their taxation:
1st. As to mutual savings banks. -- Under income tax laws prior to 1870, these
institutions were specifically taxed. Under the new law, [**696]
certain institutions of this class are exempt, provided the shareholders do not
participate in the profits, and interest and dividends are only paid to the
depositors. No limit is fixed to the property and income thus exempted -- it
may be $ 100,000 or $ 100,000,000.One of the counsel engaged in this case read
to us during the argument from the report of the Comptroller of the Currency,
sent by the President to Congress December 3, 1894, a statement to the effect
that the total number of mutual savings banks exempted was 646, and the total
number of stock savings banks was 378, and showed that they did the same
character of business and took in the money of depositors for the purpose of
making it bear interest, with profit upon it in the same way; and yet the 646
are exempt and the 378 are taxed. He also showed that the total deposits in
savings banks were $ 1,748,000,000. [***303]
2d. As to mutual insurance corporations. -- These companies were taxed under
previous income tax laws. They do business somewhat differently from other
companies; but they conduct a strictly private business in which the public has
no interest, and have been often held not to be benevolent or charitable
organizations.
[*598] The sole condition for exempting them under the present law
is declared to be that they make loans to or divide their profits among their
members, or depositors or policy-holders. Every corporation is carried on,
however, for the benefit of its members, whether stockholders, or depositors,
or policyholders. If it is carried on for the benefit of its shareholders,
every dollar of income is taxed; if it is carried on for the benefit of its
policy-holders or depositors, who are but another class of shareholders, it is
wholly exempted. In the State of New York the act exempts the income from over
$ 1,000,000,000 of property of these companies. The leading mutual life
insurance company has property exceeding $ 204,000,000 in value, the income of
which is wholly exempted. The insertion of the exemption is stated by counsel
to have saved that institution fully [***304] $ 200,000 a year over
other insurance companies and associations, having similar property and
carrying on the same business, simply because such other companies or associations
divide their profits among their shareholders instead of their policy-holders.
3d. As to building and loan associations. -- The property of these institutions
is exempted from taxation to the extent of millions. They are in no sense
benevolent or charitable institutions, and are conducted solely for the
pecuniary profit of their members. Their assets exceed the capital stock of the
national banks of the country. One, in Dayton, Ohio, has a capital of $
10,000,000, and Pennsylvania has $ 65,000,000 invested in these associations.
The census report submitted to Congress by the President, May 1, 1894, shows
that their property in the United States amounts to over $ 628,000,000. Why
should these institutions and their immense accumulations of property be
singled out for the special favor of Congress and be freed from their just,
equal, and proportionate share of taxation when others engaged under different
names, in similar business, are subjected to taxation by this law? The
aggregate amount of the saving [***305] to these associations, by
reason of their exemption, is over $ 600,000 a year. If this statement of the
exemptions of corporations under the law of Congress, taken from the carefully
prepared briefs of counsel [*599] and from reports to Congress,
will not satisfy parties interested in this case that the act in question
disregards, in almost every line and provision, the rule of uniformity required
by the Constitution, then "neither will they be persuaded, though one rose
from the dead." That there should be any question or any doubt on the
subject surpasses my comprehension. Take the case of mutual savings banks and
stock savings banks. They do the same character of business, and in the same
way use the money of depositors, loaning it at interest for profit, yet 646 of
them, under the law before us, are exempt from taxation on their income and 378
are taxed upon it. How the tax on the income of one kind of these banks can be
said to be laid upon any principle of uniformity, when the other is exempt from
all taxation, I repeat, surpasses my comprehension.
But there are other considerations against the law which are equally decisive.
They relate to the uniformity and equality [***306] required in all
taxation, national and State; to the invalidity of taxation by the United
States of the income of the bonds and securities of the States and of their
municipal bodies; and the invalidity of the taxation of the salaries of the
judges of the United States courts.
As stated by counsel: "There is no such thing in the theory of our
national government as unlimited power of taxation in Congress. There are
limitations," as he justly observes, "of its powers arising out of
the essential nature of all free governments; there are reservations of
individual rights, without which society could not exist, and which are
respected by every government. The right of taxation is subject to these
limitations." Loan Association v. Topeka, 20 Wall. 655, and Parkersburg v.
Brown, 106 U.S. 487.
The inherent and fundamental nature and character of a tax is that of a
contribution to the support of the government, levied upon the principle of
equal and uniform apportionment among the persons taxed, and any other exaction
does not come within the legal definition of a tax.
This inherent limitation upon the taxing power forbids the imposition of taxes
which are unequal in their [***307] operation upon
[*600] similar kinds of property, and necessarily strikes down the
gross and arbitrary distinction in the income law as passed by Congress. The
[**697] law, as we have seen, distinguishes in the taxation between
corpoations by exempting the property of some of them from taxation and levying
the tax on the property of others when the corporations do not materially
differ from one another in the character of their business or in the protection
required by the government. Trifling differences in their modes of business,
but not in their results, are made the ground and occasion of the greatest
possible differences in the amount of taxes levied upon their income, showing
that the action of the legislative power upon them has been arbitrary and
capricious and sometimes merely fanciful.
There was another position taken in this case which is not the least surprising
to me of the many advanced by the upholders of the law, and that is, that if
this court shall declare that the exemptions and exceptions from taxation,
extended to the various corporations mentioned, fire, life, and marine
insurance companies, and to mutual savings banks, building, and loan
associations, [***308] violate the requirement of uniformity, and
are therefore void, the tax as to such corporations can be enforced, and that
the law will stand as though the exemptions had never been inserted. This
position does not, in my judgment, rest upon any solid foundation of law or
principe. The abrogation or repeal of an unconstitutional or illegal provision
does not operate to create and give force to any enactment or part of an
enactment which Congress as not sanctioned and promulgated. Seeming support of
this singular position is attributed to the decision of this court in
Huntington v. Worthen, 120 U.S. 97. But the examination of that case will show
that it does not give the slightest sanction to such a doctrine. There the
constitution of Arkansas had provided that all property subject to taxation
should be taxed according to its value, to be ascertained in such manner as the
general assembly should direct, making the same equal and uniform throughout
the State, and certain public property was declared by statute to be exempt
from taxation, which statute was subsequenty held to be unconstitutional. The
court decided that the unconstitutional [*601] part of the
enactment, which was [***309] separable from the remainder, could
be omitted and the remainder enforced; a doctrine undoubtedly sound, and which
has never, that I am awae of, been questioned. But that is entirely different
from the position here taken, that exempted things can be taxed by striking out
their exemption.
The law of 1894 says there shall be assessed, levied, and collected,
"except as herein otherwise provided," two per centum of the amount,
etc. If the exceptions are stricken out there is nothing to be assessed and
collected except what Congress has otherwise affirmatively ordered. Nothing
less can have the force of law. This court is impotent to pass any law on the
subject. It has no legislative power. I am unable, therefore, to see how we
can, by declaring an exemption or exception invalid, thereby give effect to
provisions as though they were never exempted. The court by declaring the
exemptions invalid cannot by any conceivable ingenuity give operative force as
enacting clauses to the exempting provisions. That result is not within the
power of man.
The law is also invalid in its provisions authorizing the taxation of the bonds
and securities of the States and of their municipal bodies.It
[***310] is objected that the case pending before us do not allege
any threatened attempt to tax the bonds or securities of the State, but only of
municipal bodies of the States. The law applies to both kinds of bonds and
securities, those of the States as well as those of municipal bodies, and the
law of Congress, we are examining, being of a public nature, affecting the
whole community, having been brought before us and assailed as unconstitutional
in some of its provisions, we are at liberty, and I think it is our duty to
refer to other unconstitutional features brought to our notice in examining the
law, though the particular points of their objection may not have been
mentioned by counsel. These bonds and securities are as important to the
performance of the duties of the State as like bonds and securities of the
United States are important to the performance of their duties, and are as
exempt from the taxation of the United States as the former are exempt from the
taxation of the States. As stated by Judge [*602] Cooley in his
work on the principles of constitutional law: "The power to tax, whether
by the United States or by the States, is to be construed in the light of, and
[***311] limited by, the fact, that the States and the Union are
inseparable, and that the Constitution contemplates the perpetual maintenance
of each with all its constitutional powers, unembarrassed and unimpaired by any
action of the other. The taxing power of the Federal government does not
therefore extend to the means or agencies through or by the employment of which
the States perform their essential functions, since, if these wee within its
reach, they might be embarrassed, and perhaps wholly paralyzed, by the burdens
it should impose.'That the power to tax involves the power to destroy; that the
power to destroy may defeat and render useless the power to create; that there
is a plain repuganance in conferring on one government a power to control the
constitutional measures of another, which other, in respect to those very
measures, is declared to be supreme over that which exerts the control, -- are
propositions not to be denied.' It is true that taxation does not necessarily
and unavoidably destroy, and that to carry it to the excess of destruction
would be an abuse not to be anticipated; [**698] but the very power
would take from the States a portion of [***312] their intended
liberty of independent action within the sphere of their powers, and would
constitute to the State a perpetual danger of embarrassment and possible
annihilation. The Constitution contemplates no such shackles upon state powers,
and by implication forbids them."
The Internal Revenue Act of June 30, 1864, in section 122, provided that
railroad and certain other companies specified, indebted for money for which
bonds had been issued, upon which interest was stipulated to be paid, should be
subject to pay a tax of five per cent on the amount of all such interest, to be
paid by the corporations and by them deducted from the interest payable to the
holders of such bonds; and the question arose in United States v. Railroad Co.,
17 Wall. 322, 327, whether the tax imposed could be thus collected from the
revenues of a city owning such bonds. This court answered the question as
follows: "There is no dispute about the general [*603] rules
of the law applicable to this subject. The power of taxation by the Federal
government upon the subjects and in the manner prescribed by the act we are
considering, is undoubted. There are, however, certain departments which are
excepted [***313] from the general power. The right of the States
to administer their own affairs through their legislative, executive, and
judicial departments, in their own manner through their own agencies, is
conceded by the uniform decisions of this court, and by the practice of the
Federal government from its organization. This carries with it an exemption of
those agencies and instruments from the taxing power of the Federal government.
If they may be taxed lightly, they may be taxed heavily; if justly,
oppressively. Their operation may be impeded and may be destroyed, if any
interference is permitted. Hence, the beginning of such taxation is not allowed
on the one side, is not claimed on the other."
And again: "A municipal corporation like the city of Baltimore is a
representative not only of the State, but it is a portion of its governmental
power.It is one of its creatures, made for a specific purpose, to exercise
within a limited sphere the powers of the State. The State may withdraw these
local powers of government at pleasure, and may, through its legislature or
other appointed channels, govern the local territory as it governs the State at
large. It may enlarge or contract its [***314] powers or destroy
its existence. As a portion of the State in the exercise of a limited portion
of the powers of the State, its revenues, like those of the State, are not
subject to taxation."
In Collector v. Day, 11 Wall. 113, 124, the court, speaking by Mr. Justice
Nelson, said: "The general government, and the States, although both exist
within the same territorial limits, are separate and distinct sovereignties,
acting separately and independently of each other, within their respective
spheres. The former in its appropriate sphere is supreme; but the States within
the limits of their powers not granted, or, in the language of the tenth
amendment, 'reserved,' are as independent of the general government as that
government within its sphere is independent of the States."
[*604] According to the census reports the bonds and securities of
the States amount to the sum of $ 1,243,268,000, on which the income or
interest exceeds the sum of $ 65,000,000 per annum, and the annual tax of two
per cent upon this income or interest would be $ 1,300,000.
The law of Congress is also invalid in that it authorizes a tax upon the
salaries of the judges of the courts of the United States, [***315]
against the declaration of the Constitution that their compensation shall not
be diminished during their continuance in office. The law declares that a tax
of two per cent shall be assessed, levied, and collected and paid annually upon
the gains, profits, and income received in the preceding calendar year, by
every citizen of the United States, whether said gains, profits, or income be
derived from any kind of property, rents, interest, dividends, or salaries, or
from any profession, trade, employment, or vocation, carried on within the
United States or elsewhere, or from any source whatever.The annual salary of a
justice of the Supreme Court of the United States is ten thousand dollars, and
this act levies a tax of two per cent on six thousand dollars of this amount,
and imposes a penalty upon those who do not make the payment, or return the
amount for taxation.
The same objection, as presented to a consideration of the objection to the
taxation of the bonds and securities of the States, as not being specially
taken in the cases before us, is urged here to a consideration of the objection
to the taxation by the law of the salaries of the judges of the courts of the
United States. [***316] The answer given to that objection may be
also given to the present one. The law of Congress being of a public nature,
affecting the interests of the whole community, and attacked for its
unconstitutionality in certain particulars, may be considered with reference to
other unconstitutional provisions called to our attention upon examining the
law, though not specifically noticed in the objections taken in the records or
briefs of counsel, that the Constitution may not be violated from the
carelessness or oversight of counsel in any particular. See O'Neil v. Vermont,
144 U.S. 323, 359.
Besides, there is a duty which this court owes to the one [*605]
hundred other United States judges who have small salaries, and who having
their compensaton reduced by the tax may be seriously affected by the law.
The Constitution of the United States provides [**699] in the first
section of article III that: "The judicial power of the United States,
shall be vested in one Supreme Court, and in such inferior courts as the
Congress may from time to time ordain and establish. The judges, both of the
Supreme and inferior courts, shall hold their offices during good behavior, and
shall, [***317] at stated times, receive for their services, a
compensation, which shall not be diminished during their continuance in
office." The act of Congress under discussion imposes, as said, a tax on
six thousand dollars of this compensation, and therefore diminishes, each year,
the compensation provided for every justice. How a similar law of Congress was
regarded thirty years ago may be shown by the following incident in which the
justices of this court were assessed at three per cent upon their salaries.
Against this Chief Justice Taney protested in a letter to Mr. Chase, then
Secretary of the Treasury, appealing to the above article in the Constitution,
and adding: "If it [his salary] can be diminished to that extent by the
means of a tax, it may, in the same way, be reduced from time to time, at the
pleasure of the legislature." He explained in his letter the object of the
constitutional inhibition thus: --
"The judiciary is one of the three great departments of the government
created and established by the Constitution. Its duties and powers are
specifically set forth, and are of a character that require it to be perfectly
independent of the other departments. And [***318] in order to
place it beyond the reach, and above even the suspicion, of any such influence,
the power to reduce their compensation is expressly withheld from Congress and
excepted from their powers of legislation.
"Language could not be more plain than that used in the Constitution. It
is, moreover, one of its most important and essential provisions. For the
articles which limit the powers of the legislative and executive branches of
the government, and those which provide safeguards for the protection of the
citizen in his person and property, would be of little value [*606]
without a judiciary to uphold and maintain them which was free from every
influence, direct or indirect, that might by possibility, in times of political
excitement, warp their judgment.
"Upon these grounds I regard an act of Congress retaining in the Treasury
a portion of the compensation of the judges as unconstitutional and void."
This letter of Chief Justice Taney was addressed to Mr. Chase, then Secretary
of the Treasury and afterwards the successor of Mr. Taney as Chief Justice. It
was dated February 16, 1863, but as no notice was taken of it, on the 10th of
March following, at the request [***319] of the Chief Justice, the
Court ordered that his letter to the Secretary of the Treasury be entered on
the records of the court, and it was so entered. See Appendix, post, 701. And
in the Memoir of the Chief Justice it is stated that the letter was, by this
order, preserved "to testify to future ages that in war, no less than in
peace, Chief Justice Taney strove to protect the Constitution from
violation."
Subsequently, in 1869, and during the administration of President Grant, when
Mr. Boutwell was Secretary of the Treasury and Mr. Hoar, of Massachusetts, was
Attorney General, there were in several of the statutes of the United States,
for the assessment and collection of internal revenue, provisions for taxing
the salaries of all civil officers of the United States, which included, in
their literal application, the salaries of the President and of the juges of
the United States. The question arose whether the law which imposed such a tax
upon them was constitutional. The opinion of the Attorney General thereon was requested
by the Secretary of the Treasury. The Attorney General, in reply, gave an
elaborate opinion advising the Secretary of the Treasury that no income tax
could [***320] be lawfully assessed and collected upon the salaries
of those officers who were in office at the time the statute imposing the tax
was passed, holding on this subject the views expressed by Chief Justice Taney.
His opinion is published in volume XIII of the Opinions of the Attorneys
General, at page 161. I am informed that it has been followed
[*607] ever since without question by the department supervising or
directing the collection of the public revenue.
Here I close my opinion. I could not say less in view of questions of such
gravity that go down to the very foundaton of the government. If the provisions
of the Constitution can be set aside by an act of Congress, where is the course
of usurpation to end? The present assault upon capital is but the beginning. It
will be but the stepping-stone to others, larger and more sweeping, till our
political contests will become a war of the poor against the rich; a war
constantly growing in intensity and bitterness.
"If the court sanctions the power of discriminating taxation, and
nullifies the uniformity mandate of the Constitution," as said by one who
has been all his life a student of our institutions, "it will mark the
[***321] hour when the sure decadence of our present government
will commence." If the purely arbitrary limitation of $ 4000 in the
present law can be sustained, none having less than that amount of income being
assessed or taxed for the support of the government, the limitation of future
Congresses may be fixed at a much larger sum, at five or ten or twenty thousand
dollars, parties possessing an income of that amount alone being bound to bear
the burdens of government; or the limitation may be designated at such an
amount as a board of "walking delegates" may deem necessary. There is
no safety in allowing the limitation to be adjusted except in strict compliance
with the mandates of the Constitution which require its taxation, if imposed by
direct taxes, [**700] to be apportioned among the States according
to their representation, and if imposed by indirect taxes, to be uniform in
operation and, so far as practicable, in proportion to their property, equal
upon all citizens. Unless the rule of the Constitution governs, a majority may
fix the limitation at such rate as will not include any of their own number.
I am of opinion that the whole law of 1894 should be declared void and without
[***322] any binding force -- that part which relates to the tax on
the rents, profits or income from real estate, that is, so much as constitutes
part of the direct tax, because, not imposed by the rule of apportionment according
[*608] to the representation of the States, as prescribed by the
Constition -- and that part which imposes a tax upon the bonds and securities
of the several States, and upon the bonds and securities of their municipal
bodies, and upon the salaries of judges of the courts of the United States, as
being beyond the power of Congress; and that part which lays duties, imposts,
and excises, as void in not providing for the uniformity required by the
Constitution in such cases.
DISSENTBY: WHITE; HARLAN
DISSENT: MR. JUSTICE WHITE, with whom concurred MR. JUSTICE
HARLAN, dissenting.
My brief judicial experience has convinced me that the custom of filing long
dissenting opinions is one "more honored in the breach than in the
observance." The only purpose which an elaborate dissent can accomplish,
if any, is to weaken the effect of the opinion of the majority, and thus
engender want of confidence in the conclusions of courts of last resort. This
consideration [***323] would impel me to content myself with simply
recording my dissent in the present case, were it not for the fact that I
consider that the result of the opinion of the court just announced is to
overthrow a long and consistent line of decisions, and to deny to the
legislative department of the government the possession of a power conceded to
it by universal consensus for one hundred years, and which has been recognized
by repeated adjudications of this court. The issues presented are as follows:
Complainant, as a stockholder in a corporation, avers that the latter will
voluntarily pay the income tax, levied under the recent act of Congress; that
such tax is unconstitutional; and that its voluntary payment will seriously
affect his interest by defeating his right to test the validity of the
exaction, and also lead t a multiplicity of suits against the corporation. The
prayer of the bill is as follows: First. That it may be decreed that the
provisions known as "The Income Tax Law," incorporated in the act of
Congress, passed August 15, 1894, are unconstitutional, null, and void. Second.
That the defendant be restrained from voluntarily complying with the provisions
of that act by [***324] making its returns and statements,
[*609] and paying the tax. The bill, therefore, presents two
substantial questions for decision: the right of the plaintiff to relief in the
form in which he claims it; and his right to relief on the merits.
The decisions of this court hold that the collection of a tax levied by the
government of the United States, will not be restrained by its courts. Cheatham
v. United States, 92 U.S. 85; Snyder v. Marks, 109 U.S. 189. See also Elliott
v. Swartwout, 10 Pet. 137; City of Philadelphia v. The Collector, 5 Wall. 720;
Hornthall v. The Collector, 9 Wall. 560. The same authorities have established
the rule that the proper course, in a case of illegal taxation, is to pay the
tax under protest or with notice of suit, and then bring an action against the
officer who collected it. The statute law of the United States, in express
terms, gives a party who has paid a tax under protest the right to sue for its
recovery. Rev. Stat. § 3226.
The act of 1867 forbids the maintenance of any suit "for the purpose of
restraining the assessment or collection of any tax." The provisions of
this act are now found in Rev. Stat. § 3224.
The complainant is [***325] seeking to do the very thing which,
according to the statute and the decisions above referred to, may not be done.
If the corporator cannot have the collection of the tax enjoined it seems obvious
that he cannot have the corporation enjoined from paying it, and thus do by
indirection what he cannot do directly.
It is said that such relief as is here sought has been frequently allowed. The
cases relied on are Dodge v. Woolsey, 18 How. 331, and Hawes v. Oakland, 104
U.S. 450. Neither of these authorities, I submit, is in point. In Dodge v.
Woolsey, the main question at issue was the validity of a state tax, and that
case did not involve the act of Congress to which I have referred. Hawes v.
Oakland was a controversy between a stockholder and a corporation, and had no
reference whatever to taxation.
The complainant's attempt to establish a right to relief upon the gound that
this is not a suit to enjoin the tax, but [*610] one to enjoin the
corporation from paying it, involves the fallacy already pointed out -- that
is, that a party can exercise a right indirectly which he cannot assert
directly -- that he can compel his agent, through process of this court, to
violate an [***326] act of Congress.
The rule which forbids the granting of an injunction to restrain the collection
of a tax is founded on broad reasons of public policy and should not be
ignored. In Cheatham v. United States, 92 U.S. 85, 89, which involved the
validity of an income tax levied under an act of Congress prior to the one here
in issue, this court, through Mr. Justice Miller, said:
"If there existed in the courts, state or National, any general power of
impeding or controlling the collection of taxes, or relieving the hardship
incident to taxation, the very existence of the government might be
[**701] placed in the power of a hostile judiciary. Dows v. The
City of Chicago, 11 Wall. 108. While a free course of remonstrance and appeal
is allowed within the departments before the money is finally exacted, the
general government has wisely made the payment of the tax claimed, whether of
customs or of internal revenue, a condition precedent to a resort to the courts
by the party against whom the tax is assessed. In the internal revenue branch
it has further prescribed that no such suit shall be brought until he remedy by
appeal has been tried; and, if brought after this, it must be
[***327] within six months after the decision on the appeal. We
regard this as a condition on which alone the government consents to litigate
the lawfulness of the original tax. It is not a hard condition. Few governments
have conceded such a right on any condition. If the compliance with this
condition requires the party aggrieved to pay the money, he must do it."
92 U.S. 85, 89.
Again, in Railroad Tax Cases, 92 U.S. 575, 613, the court said: "That
there might be no misunderstanding of the universality of this principle, it
was expressly enacted, in 1867, that 'no suit for the purpose of restraining
the assessment or collection of any tax shall be maintained in any court.' Rev.
Stat. sect. 3224. And though this was intended to apply alone to taxes levied
by the United States, it shows the sense [*611] of Congress of the
evils to be feared if courts of justice could, in any case, interfere with the
process of collecting the taxes on which the government depends for its
continued existence. It is a wise policy. It is founded in the simple
philosophy derived from the experience of ages, that the payment of taxes has
to be enforced by summary and stringent means against a reluctant
[***328] and often adverse sentiment; and to do this successfully,
other instrumentalities and other modes of procedure are necessary, than those
which belong to courts of justice. See Cheatham v. Norvell, decided at this
term; Nicoll v. United States, 7 Wall. 122; Dows v. Chicago, 11 Wall.
108."
The contention that a right to equitable relief arises from the fact that the
corporator is without remedy unless such relief be granted him is, I think,
without foundation. This court has repeatedly said that the illegality of a tax
is not ground for the issuance of an injunction against its collection if there
be an adequate remedy at law open to the payer. Dows v. City of Chicago, 11
Wall. 108; Hannewinkle v. Georgetown, 15 Wall. 547; Board of Liquidation v.
McComb, 92 U.S. 531; State Railroad Tax Cases, 92 U.S. 575; Union Pacific
Railway v. Cheyenne, 113 U.S. 516; Milwaukee v. Koeffler, 116 U.S. 219; Pacific
Express Co. v. Seibert, 142 U.S. 339 -- as in the case where the state statute,
by which the tax is imposed, allows a suit for its recovery after payment under
protest. Shelton v. Platt, 139 U.S. 591; Allen v. Pullman's Palace Car Co., 139
U.S. 658.
The decision here is, [***329] that tis court will allow, on the
theory of equitable right, a remedy expressly forbidden by the statutes of the
United States, though it has denied the existence of such a remedy in the case
of a tax levied by a State.
Will it be said that, although a stockholder cannot have a corporation enjoined
from paying a state tax where the state statute gives him the right to sue for
its recovery, yet when the United States not only gives him such right, but, in
addition, forbids the issue of an injunction to prevent the payment of Federal
taxes, the court will allow to the stockholder [*612] a remedy
against the United States tax which it refuses against the state tax?
The assertion that this is only a suit to prevent the voluntary payment of the
tax suggests that the court may, by an order operating directly upon the
defendant corporation, accomplish a result which the statute manifestly
intended should not be accomplished by suit in any court. A final judgment
forbidding the corporation from paying the tax will have the effect to prevent
its collection, for it could not be that the court would permit a tax to be
collected from a corporation which it had enjoined from paying. I
[***330] take it to be beyond dispute that the collection of the
tax in question cannot be restrained by any proceeding or suit, whatever its
form, directly against the officer charged with the duty of collecting such
tax. Can the statute be evaded, in a suit between a corporation and a
stockholder, by a judgment forbidding the former from paying the tax, the
collection of which cannot be restrained by suit in any court? Suppose,
notwithstanding the final judgment just rendered, the collector proceeds to
collect from the defendant corporation the taxes which the court declares, in
this suit, cannot be legally assessed upon it. If that final judgment is
sufficient in law to justify resistance against such collection, then we have a
case in whcih a suit has been maintained to restrain the collection of taxes.If
such judgment does not conclude the collector, who was not a party to the suit
in which it was rendered, then it is of no value to the plaintiff. In other
words, no form of expression can conceal the fact that the real object of this
suit is to prevent the collection of taxes imposed by Congress, notwithstanding
the express statutory requirement that "no suit for the purpose of
restraining [***331] the assessment or collection of any tax shall
be maintained in any court." Either the decision of the constitutional
question is necessary, or it is not. If it is necessary, then the court, by way
of granting equitable relief, does the very thing which the act of Congress
forbids. If it is unnecessary, then the court decides the act of Congress here
asserted unconstitional, without being obliged [**702] to do so by
the requirements of the case before it.
[*613] This brings me to the consideration of the merits of the
cause.
The constitutional provisions respecting Federal taxation are four in number,
and are as follows:
1. "Representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned among the
several States, which may be included within this Union, according to their
respective numbers, which shall be determined by adding to the whole number of
free persons, including those bound to service for a term of years and
excluding Indians not taxed, three-fifths of all other persons." Art. I,
sec. 2, clause 3. (The Fourteenth Amendment modified this provision, so that
the whole number of persons in each State should be counted, "Indians not
taxed" excluded.)
2. "The Congress [***332] shall have power to lay and collect
taxes, duties, imposts, and excises, to pay the debts and provide for the
common defence and general welfare of the United States; but all duties,
imposts, and excises shall be uniform throughout the United States." Art.
I, sec. 8, clause 1.
3. "No capitation or other direct tax shall be laid, unless in proportion
to the census or enumeration hereinbefore directed to be taken." Art. I,
sec. 9, clause 4.
4."No tax or duty shall be laid on articles exported from any State."
Art. I, sec. 9, clause 5.
It has been suggested that, as the above provisions ordain the apportionment of
direct taxes, and authorize Congress to "lay and collect taxes, duties,
imposts, and excises," therefore, there is a class of taxes which are
neither direct, and are not duties, imposts, and excises, and are exempt from
the rule of apportionment on the one hand or of uniformity on the other. The
soundness of this suggestion need not be discussed, as the words, "duties,
imposts, and excises," in conjunction with the reference to direct taxes,
adequately convey all power of taxation to the Federal government.
It is not necessary to pursue this branch of the argument, [***333]
since it is unquestioned that the provisions of the Constitution vest in the
United States plenary powers of taxation, that is, all the powers which belong
to a government as such, except [*614] that of taxing exports. The
court in this case so says, and quotes approvingly the language of this court,
speaking through Mr. Chief Justice Chase, in License Tax Cases, 5 Wall. 462,
471, as follows:
"It is true that the power of Congress to tax is a very extensive power.
It is given in the Constitution with only one exception and only two
qualifications. Congress cannot tax exports, and it must impose direct taxes by
the rule of apportionment, and indirect taxes by the rule of uniformity. Thus
limited and thus only, it reaches every subject and may be exercised at
discretion."
In deciding, then, the question of whether the income tax violates the
Constitution, we have to determine not the exsitence of a power in Congress,
but whether an admittedly unlimited power to tax (the income tax not being a
tax on exports) has been used according to the restrictions as to methods for
its exercise, found in the Constitution. Not power, it must be borne in mind,
but the manner [***334] of its use is the only issue presented in
this case. The limitations in regard to the mode of direct taxation imposed by
the Constitution are that capitation and other direct taxes shall be
apportioned among the States according to their respective numbers, while
duties, imposts, and excises must be uniform throughout the United States. The
meaning of the word "uniform" in the Constitution need not be
examined, as the court is divided upon that subject, and no expression of
opinion thereon is conveyed or intended to be conveyed in this dissent.
In considering whether we are to regard an income tax as "direct" or
otherwise, it will, in my opinion, serve no useful purpose, at this late period
of our political history, to seek to ascertain the meaning of the word
"direct" in the Constitution by resorting to the theoretical opinions
on taxation found in the writings of some economists prior to the adoption of
the Constitution or since. These economists teach that the question of whether
a tax is direct or indirect, depends not upon whether it is directly levied
upon a person but upon whether, when so levied, it may be ultimately shifted
from the person [*615] in question to the [***335]
consumer, thus becoming, while direct in the method of its application,
indirect in its final results, because it reaches the person who really pays it
only indirectly. I say it will serve no useful purpose to examine these
writers, because whatever may have been the value of their opinions as to the
economic sense of the word "direct," they cannot now afford any
criterion for determining its meaning in the Constitution, inasmuch as an
authoritative and conclusive construction has been given to that term, as there
used by an interpretation adopted shortly after the formation of the
Constitution by the legislative department of the government, and approved by
the Executive; by the adoption of that interpretation from that time to the
present without question, and its exemplification and enforcement in many
legislative enactments, and its acceptance by the authoritative text-writers on
the Constitution; by the sanction of that interpretation, in a decision of this
court rendered shortly after the Constitution was adopted; and finally by the
repeated reiteration and affirmance of that interpretation, so that it has
become imbedded in our jurisprudence, and therefore may be considered
[***336] almost a part of the written Constitution itself.
Instead, therefore, of following counsel in their references to economic
writers and their [**703] discussion of the motives and thoughts
which may or may not have been present in the minds of some of the framers of
the Constitution, as if the question before us were one of first impression, I
shall confine myself to a demonstration of the truth of the propositions just
laid down.
By the act of June 5, 1794, c. 45, 1 Stat. 373, Congress levied, without
reference to apportionment, a tax on carriages "for the conveyance of
persons." The act provided "that there shall be levied, collected,
and paid upon all carriages for the conveyance of persons which shall be kept
by, or for any person for his or her own use, or to be let out to hire, or for
the conveying of passengers, the several duties and rates following;" and
then came a yearly tax on every "coach, chariot, phaeton, and coachee,
every four-wheeled and every [*616] two-wheeled top carriage, and
upon every other two-wheeled carriage," varying in amount according to the
vehicle.
The debates which took place at the passage of that act are meagrely preserved.
It may, [***337] however, be inferred from them that some
considered that, whether a tax was "direct" or not in the sense of
the Constitution, depended upon whether it was levied on the object or on its
use. The carriage tax was defended by a few on the ground that it was a tax on
consumption. Mr. Madison opposed it as unconstitutional, evidently upon the
conception that the word "direct" in the Constitution was to be
considered as having the same meaning as that which had been attached to it by
some economic writers.His view was not sustained, and the act passed by a large
majority -- forty-nine to twenty-two. It received the approval of
Washington.The Congress which passed this law numbered among its members many
who sat in the convention which framed the Constitution. It is moreover safe to
say that each member of that Congress, even although he had not been in the
convention, had, in some way, either directly or indirectly, been an
influential actor in the events which led up to the birth of that instrument.
It is impossible to make an analysis of this act which will not show that its
provisions constitute a rejection of the economic construction of the word
"direct," and this result equally [***338] follows,
whether the tax be treated as laid on the carriage itself or on its use by the
owner. If viewed in one light, then the imposition of the tax on the owner of
the carriage, because of his ownership, necessarily constituted a direct tax
under the rule as laid down by economists. So, also, the imposition of a burden
of taxation on the owner for the use by him of his own carriage made the tax
direct according to the same rule. The tax having been imposed without
apportionment, it follows that those who voted for its enactment must have
given to the word direct, in the Constitution, a different significance from
that which is affixed to it by the economists referred to.
The validity of this carriage tax was considered by this court in Hylton v. The
United States, 3 Dall. 171. Chief Justice Ellsworth and Mr. Justice Cushing
took no part in [*617] the decision. Mr. Justice Wilson stated that
he had, in the Circuit Court of Virginia, expressed his opinion in favor of the
constitutionality of the tax. Mr. Justice Chase, Mr. Justice Paterson, and Mr.
Justice Iredell each expressed the reasons for his conclusions. The tax though
laid, as I have said, on the carriage, [***339] was held not to be
a direct tax under the Constitution. Two of the judges who sat in that case
(Mr. Justice Paterson and Mr. Justice Wilson) had been distinguished members of
the constitutional convention. Excerpts from the observations of the justices
are given in the opinion of the court. Mr. Justice Paterson, in addition to the
language there quoted, spoke as follows, p. 177 (the italics being mine):
"I never entertained a doubt that the principal, I will not say the only,
objects that the framers of the Constitution contemplated as falling within the
rule of apportionment were a capitation tax and a tax on land. Local
considerations, and the particular circumstances and relative situation of the
States, naturally lead to this view of the subject. The provision was made in
favor of the Southern States.They possessed a large number of salves; they had
extensive tracts of territory, thinly settled, and not very productive. A
majority of the States had but few slaves, and several of them a limited
territory, well settled, and in a high state of cultivation. The Southern
States, if no provision had been introduced in the Constitution, would have
been wholly at the mercy of the [***340] other States. Congress, in
such case, might tax slaves at discretion or arbitrarily, and land in every
part of the Union after the same rate or measure -- so much a head in the first
instance and so much an acre in the second. To guard them against imposition in
these particulars was the reason of introducing the clause in the Constitution,
which directs that representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned among
the States according to their respective numbers."
It is evident that Mr. Justice Chase coincided with these views of Mr. Justice
Paterson, though he was perhaps not quite so firmly settled in his convictions,
for he said, p. 176:
"I am inclined to think, but of this I do not give a judicial
[*618] opinion, that the direct taxes contemplated by the
Constitution are only two, to wit, a capitation or poll tax simply, without
regard to property, profession, or any other circumstances, and the tax on
land. I doubt whether a tax by a general assessment of personal property within
the United States is included within the term 'direct tax.'"
Mr. Justice Iredell certainly entertained similar views, since he said, p. 183:
"Some difficulties may occur which we do [***341] not at
present foresee. Perhaps a direct tax in the sense of the Constitution can mean
[**704] nothing but a tax on something inseparably annexed to the
soil; something capable of apportionment under all such circumstances. A land
or poll tax may be considered of this description . . . In regard to other
articles there may possibly be considerable doubt."
These opinions strongly indicate that the real convictions of the justices were
that only capitation taxes and taxes on land were direct within the meaning of
the Constitution, but they doubted whether some other objects of a kindred
nature might not be embraced in that word. Mr. Justice Paterson had no doubt
whatever of the limitation, and Justice Iredell's doubt seems to refer only to
things which were inseparably connected with the soil, and which might
therefore be considered, in a certain sense, as real estate.
That case, however, established that a tax levied without apportionment on an
object of personal property was not a "direct tax" within the meaning
of the Constitution. There can be no doubt that the enactment of this tax and
its interpretation by the court, as well as the suggestion in the opinions
delivered, [***342] that nothing was a direct tax within the
meaning of the Constitution but a capitation tax and a tax on land, was all
directly in conflict with the views of those who claimed at the time that the
word "direct" in the Constitution was to be interpreted according to
the views of economists. This is conclusively shown by Mr. Madison's language.
He asserts not only that the act had been passed contrary to the Constitution,
but that the decision of the court was likewise in violation of that
instrument. Ever since the announcement [*619] of the decision in
that case the legislative department of the government has accepted the
opinions of the justices as well as the decision itself as conclusive in regard
to the meaning of the word "direct," and it has acted upon that
assumption in many instances and always with Executive endorsement. All the
acts passed levying direct taxes confined them practically to a direct levy on
land.True in some of these acts a tax on slaves was included, but this
inclusion, as has been said by this court, was probably based upon the theory
that these were in some respects taxable along with the land, and, therefore,
their inclusion indicated [***343] no departure by Congress from
the meaning of the word "direct," necessarily resulting from the
decision in the Hylton case, and which, moreover, had been expressly elucidated
and suggested as being practically limited to capitation taxes and taxes on
real estate by the justices who expressed opinions in that case.
These acts imposing direct taxes having been confined in their operation
exclusively to real estate and slaves, the subject-matters indicated as the
proper object of direct taxation in the Hylton case, are the strongest possible
evidence that this suggestion was accepted as conclusive and had become a
settled rule of law. Some of these acts were passed at times of great public
necessity when revenue was urgently required. The fact that no other subjects
were selected for the purposes of direct taxation, except those which the
judges in the Hylton case had suggested as appropriate therefor, seems to me to
lead to a conclusion which is absolutely irresistible -- that the meaning thus
affixed to the word "direct" at the very formation o the government
was considered as having been as irrevocably determined, as if it had been
written in the Constitution in express terms. [***344] As I have
already observed, every authoritative writer who has discussed the Constitution
from that date down to this has treated this judicial and legislative
ascertainment of the meaning of the word "direct" in the Constitution
as giving it a constitutional significance without reference to the theoretical
distinction between "direct" and "indirect," made by some
economists prior to the Constitution, or since. This doctrine
[*620] has become a part of the horn-book of American
constitutional interpretation, has been taught as elementary in all the law
schools, and has never since then been anywhere authoritatively questioned. Of
course, the text-books may conflict in some particulars, or indulge in
reasoning not always consistent, but as to the effect of the decision in the
Hylton case, and the meaning of the word "direct," in the
Constitution, resulting therefrom, they are a unit.I quote briefly from them.
Chancellor Kent, in his Commentaries thus states the principle:
"The construction of the powers of Congress relative to taxation was
brought before the Supreme Court, in 1796, in the case of Hylton v. The United
States. By the act of 5th June, 1794, Congress laid a [***345] duty
upon carriages for the conveyance of persons, and the question was whether this
was a direct tax, within the meaning of the Constitution. If it was not a
direct tax, it was admitted to be rightly laid, under that part of the
Constitution which declares that all duties, imposts, and excises shall be
uniform throughout the United States; but if it was a direct tax it was not
constitutionally laid, for it must then be laid according to the census, under
that part of the Constitution which declares that direct taxes shall be
apportioned among the several States according to numbers. The Circuit Court in
Virginia was divided in opinion on the question, but on appeal to the Supreme
Court it was decided that the tax on carriages was not a direct tax, within the
letter or meaning of th Constitution, and was therefore constitutionally laid.
"The question was deemed of very great importance, and was elaborately
argued. It was held that a general power was given to Congress to lay and
collect taxes of every kind or nature, without any restraint. They had plenary
power over every species of taxable property, except exports. But there were
two rules prescribed for their government: [***346] the rule of
uniformity, and the rule of apportionment. Three kinds of taxes, viz.,
[**705] duties, imposts, and excises, were to be laid by the first
rule; and capitation, and other direct taxes, by the second rule. If there were
any other species of taxes, as the [*621] court seemed to suppose
there might be, that were not direct, and not included within the words duties,
imposts, or excises, they were to be laid by the rule of uniformity or not, as
Congress should think proper and reasonable.
"The Constitution contemplated no taxes as direct taxes, but such as
Congress could lay in proportion to the census; and the rule of apportionment
could not reasonably apply to a tax on carriages, nor could the tax on
carriages be laid by that rule without very great inequality and injustice. If
two states, equal in census, were each to pay 8000 dollars by a tax on
carriages, and in one state there were 100 carriages and in another 1000, the
tax on each carriage would be ten times as much in one state as in the other.
While A, in the one state, would pay for his carriage eight dollars, B, in the
other state, would pay for his carriage eighty dollars. In this way it was
shown [***347] by the court that the notion that a tax on carriages
was a direct tax within the purview of the Constitution, and to be apportioned
according to the census, would lead to the grossest abuse and oppression. This
argument was conclusive against the construction set up, and the tax on
carriages was considered as included within the power to lay duties; and the
better opinion seemed to be that the direct taxes contemplated by the
Constitution were only two, viz., a capitation or poll tax and a tax on
land." 1 Kent Com. 254, 56.
Story, speaking on the same subject, 1 Story Const. § 955, says: "Taxes on
lands, houses, and other permanent real estate, or on parts or appurtenances
thereof, have always been deemed of the same character, that is, direct taxes.
It has been seriously doubted if, in the sense of the Constitution, any taxes
are direct taxes, except those on polls or on lands. Mr. Justice Chase, in
Hylton v. United States, 3 Dall. 171, said: 'I am inclined to think that the
direct taxes contemplated by the Constitution are only two, viz: a capitation or
poll tax simply, without regard to property, profession, or other
circumstances, and a tax on land. I doubt whether a tax [***348] by
a general assessment of personal property within the United States is included
within the term "direct tax."' Mr. Justice Paterson in the same case
said: 'It is not necessary to determine [*622] whether a tax on the
produce of land be a direct or an indirect tax. Perhaps the immediate product
of land, in its original and crude state, ought to be considered as a part of
the land itself. When the produce is converted into a manufacture, it assumes a
new shape, etc. Whether "direct taxes," in the sense of the
Constitution, comprehend any other tax than a capitation tax, or a tax on land,
is a questionable point, etc. I never entertained a doubt that the principal, I
will not say the only, objects that the framers of the Constitution
contemplated, as falling within the rule of apportionment, were a capitation
tax and a tax on land.' And he proceeded to state that the rule of
apportionment, both as regards representatives and as regards direct taxes, was
adopted to guard the Southern States against undue impositions and oppressions
in the taxing of slaves. Mr. Justice Iredell in the same case said: 'Perhaps a
direct tax, in the sense of the Constitution, can mean nothing but
[***349] a tax on something inseparably annexted to the soil;
something capable of apportionment under all such circumstances. A land or poll
tax may be considered of this description. The latter is to be considered so,
particularly under the present Constitution, on account of the slaves in the
Southern States, who give a ratio in the representation in the proportion of
three to five. Either of these is capable of an apportionment. In regard to
other articles, there may possibly be considerable doubt.' The reasoning of the
Federalist seems to lead to the same result."
Cooley, in his work on Constitutional Limitations, 595, 5th ed., marginal
paging *480, thus tersely states the rule: "Direct taxes, when laid by
Congress, must be apportioned among the several States according to the
representative population. The term 'direct taxes' as employed in the
Constitution has a technical meaning, and embraces capitation and land taxes
only."
Miller on the Constitution, 237, thus puts it: "Under the provisions
already quoted the question came up as to what is a 'direct tax,' and also upon
what property it is to be levied, as distinguished from any any other tax. In
regard to this [***350] it is sufficient to say that it is believed
that no other than a capitation tax of so much per head and a land tax is a
direct tax [*623] within the meaning of the Constitution of the
United States. All other taxes, except imposts, are properly called excise
taxes. Direct taxes, within the meaning of the Constitution, are only
capitation taxes, as expressed in that instrument, and taxes on real
estate."
In Pomeroy's Constitutional Law (§ 281) we read as follows:
"It becomes necessary, therefore, to inquire a little more particularly:
What are direct and what indirect taxes? Few cases on the general question of
taxation have arisen and been decided by the Supreme Court for the simple
reason that, until the past few years, the United States has generally been
able to obtain all needful revenue from the single source of duties upon
imports. There can be no doubt, however, that all the taxes provided for in the
internal revenue acts now in operation are indirect.
"This subject came before the Supreme Court of the United States in a very
early case, Hylton v. The United States. In the year 1794 [**706]
Congress laid a tax of ten dollars on all carriages, and the rate
[***351] was thus made uniform. The validity of the statute was
disputed; it was claimed that the tax was direct and should have been
apportioned among the states. The court decided that this tax was not direct.
The reasons given for the decision are unanswerable, and would seem to cover
all the provisions of the present internal revenue laws."
Hare, in his treatise on American Constitutional Law (vol. 1, pp. 249, 250), is
to the like effect: "Agreeably to section 9 of article I, paragraph 4, 'no
capitation or other direct tax shall be laid except in proportion to the census
or enumeration hereinbefore directed to be taken;' while section 3 of the same
article requires that representation and direct taxes shall be apportioned
among the several States . . . according to their respective numbers.Direct
taxes in the sense of the Constitution are poll taxes and taxes on land."
Burroughs on Taxation (p. 502) takes the same view: "Direct taxes -- The
kinds of taxation authorized are both direct and indirect. The construction
given to the expression 'direct taxes,' is that it includes only a tax on land
and a poll [*624] tax, and this is in accord with the views of
writers upon political [***352] economy."
Ordronaux, in his Constitutional Legislation, (p. 225), says:
"Congress having been given the power 'to lay and collect taxes, duties,
imposts, and excises,' the above three provisions are limitations upon the
exercise of this authority:
"1st. By distinguishing between direct and indirect taxes as to their mode
of assessment;
"2d. By establishing a permanent freedom of trade between the States; and
"3d. By prohibiting any discrimination in favor of particular States,
through revenue laws establishing a preference between their ports and those of
the others.
"These provisions should be read together, because they are at the
foundation of our system of national taxation.
"The two rules prescribed for the government of Congress in laying taxes
are those of apportionment for direct taxes and uniformity for indirect. In the
first class are to be found capitation or poll taxes and taxes on land; in the
second, duties, imposts, and excises. . . .
"The provision relating to capitation taxes was made in favor of the
Southern States, and for the protection of slave property. While they possessed
a large number of persons o this class, they also had extensive tracts
[***353] of sparsely settled and unproductive lands. At the same
time an opposite condition, both as to land-territory and population, existed
in a majority of th other States. Were Congress permitted to tax slaves and
land in all parts of the country at a uniform rate, the Southern Slave States
must have been placed at a great disadvantage. Hence, and to guard against this
inequality of circumstances, there was introduced into the Constitution the
further provision that 'representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned
among the States according to their respective numbers.' This changed the basis
of direct taxation from a strictly monetary standard, which could not,
equitably, be made uniform throughout the country, to one resting upon
population, as the measure of representation. But for this Congress might have
taxed slaves arbitrarily and [*625] at its pleasure as so much
property, and land uniformly throughout the Union regardless of differences in
productiveness. It is not strange, therefore, that in Hylton v. United States
the court said that 'the rule of apportionment is radically wrong, and cannot
be supported by any solid reasoning. It ought not, therefore, to be
[***354] extended by construction. Apportionment is an operation on
States and involves valuations and assessments which are arbitrary, and should
not be resorted to but in case of necessity.'
"Direct taxes being now well settled in their meaning, a tax on carriages
left for the use of the owner is not a capitation tax; nor a tax on the
business of an insurance company; nor a tax on a bank's circulation; nor a tax
on income; nor a succession tax. The foregoing are not, properly speaking,
direct taxes within the meaning of the Constitution, but excise taxes or
duties."
Black, writing on Constitutional Law, says: "But the chief difficulty has
arisen in determining what is the difference between direct taxes and such as
are indirect. In general usage, and according to the terminology of political
economy, a direct tax is one which is levied upon the person who is to pay it,
or upon his land or personalty, or his business or income, as the case may be.
An indirect tax is one assessed upon the manufacturer or dealer in the
particular commodity, and paid by him; but which really falls upon the
consumer, since it is added to the market price of the commodity which he must
pay. [***355] But the course of judicial decision has determined
that the term 'direct,' as here applied to taxes, is to be taken in a more
restricted sense. The Supreme Court has ruled that only land taxes and
capitation taxes are 'direct' and no others. In 1794 Congress levied a tax of
ten dollars on all carriages kept for use, and it was held that this was not a
direct tax. And so also an income tax is not to be considered direct. Neither
is a tax on the circulation of state banks, nor a succession tax, imposed upon
every 'devolution of title to real estate.'" Opinions cited on page 162.
Not only have the other departments of the government accepted the significance
attached to the word "direct" in the [*626] Hylton case
by their actions as to direct taxes, but they have also relied on it as
conclusive in their [**707] dealings with indirect taxes by levying
them solely upon objects which the judges in that case declared were not
objects of direct taxation. Thus the affirmance by the Federal legislature and
executive of the doctrine established as a result of the Hylton case has been
two-fold.
From 1861 to 1870 many laws levying taxes on income were enacted, as follows:
Act [***356] of August 5, 1861, c. 45, 12 Stat. 292, 309, 311; Act
of July 1, 1862, c. 119, 12 Stat. 432, 473, 475; Act of March 3, 1863, c. 74,
12 Stat. 713, 718, 723; Act of June 30, 1864, c. 173, 13 Stat. 223, 281, 285;
Act of March 3, 1865, c. 78, 13 Stat. 469, 479, 481; Act of March 10, 1866, c.
15, 14 Stat. 4, 5; Act of July 13, 1866, c. 184, 14 Stat. 98, 137, 140; Act of
March 2, 1867, c. 169, 14 Stat. 471, 477, 480; Act of July 14, 1870, c. 255, 16
Stat. 256, 261.
The statutes above referred to all cover income and every conceivable source of
revenue from which it could result -- rentals from real estate, products of
personal property, the profits of business or professions.
The validity of these laws has been tested before this court. The first case on
the subject was that of the Pacific Insurance Company v. Soule, 7 Wall. 433,
443. The controversy in that case arose under the ninth section of the act of
July 13, 1866, 14 Stat. 137, 140, which imposed a tax on "all dividends in
scrip and money, thereafter declared due, wherever and whenever the same shall
be payable, to stockholders, policy holders, or depositors or parties
whatsoever, including non-residents whether citizens or aliens,
[***357] as part of the earnings, incomes, or gains of any bank,
trust company, savings institution, and of any fire, marine, life, or inland
insurance company, either stock or mutual, under whatever name or style known
or called in the United States or Territories, whether specially incorporated or
existing under general laws, and on all undistributed sum or sums made or added
during the year to their surplus or contingent funds."
It will be seen that the tax imposed was levied on the income of insurance
companies as a unit, including every possible [*627] source of
revenue, whether from personal or real property, from business gains or
otherwise. The case was presented here on a certificate of division of opinion
below. One of the questions propounded was "whether the taxes paid by the
plaintiff and sought to be recovered in this action are not direct taxes within
the meaning of the Constitution of the United States?" The issue,
therefore, necessarily brought before this court was whether an act imposing an
income tax on every possible source of revenue was valid or invalid. The case
was carefully, ably, elaborately, and learnedly argued. The brief on behalf of
the company, filed [***358] by Mr. Wills, was supported by another
signed by Mr. W. O. Bartlett, which covered every aspect of the contention. It
rested the weight of its argument against the statute on the fact that it
included the rents of real estate among the sources of income taxed, and
therefore put a direct tax upon the land. Able as have been the arguments at
bar in the present case, an examination of those then presented will disclose
the fact that every view here urged was there pressed upon the court with the
greatest ability, and after exhaustive research, equalled but not surpassed by
the eloquence and learning which has accompanied the presentation of this case.
Indeed, it may be said that the principal authorities cited and relied on now
can be found in the arguments which were then submitted. It may be added that
the case on behalf of the government was presented by Attorney General Evarts.
The court answered all the contentions by deciding the generic question of the
validity of the tax, thus passing necessarily upon every issue raised, as the
whole necessarily includes every one of its parts. I quote the reasoning
applicable to the matter now in hand:
"The sixth questions is: 'Whether [***359] the taxes paid by
the plaintiff, and sought to be recovered back in this action, are not direct
taxes, within the meaning of the Constitution of the United States.' In
considering this subject it is proper to advert to the several provisions of
the Constitution relating to taxation by Congress. 'Representatives and direct
taxes shall be apportioned among the several States which shall be included
[*628] in this Union according to their respective numbers,' etc.
'Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and
excises, to pay the debts and provide for the common defence and general
welfare of the United States; but all duties, imposts, and excises shll be uniform
throughout the United States.' 'No capitation or other direct tax shall be
laid, unless in proportion to the census or enumeration hereinbefore directed
to be taken.' 'No tax or duty shall be laid on articles exported from any
State.'
"These clauses contain the entire grant of the taxing power by the organic
law, with the limitations which that instrument imposes.
"The national government, though supreme within its own sphere, is one of
limited jurisdiction and specific functions. It has [***360] no
faculties but such as the Constitution has given it, either expressly or
incidentally by necessary intendment. Whenever any act done under its authority
is challenged, the proper sanction must be found in its charter, or the act is
ultra vires and void. This test must be applied in the examination of the
question before us. If the tax to which it refers is a 'direct tax,' it is
clear that it has not been laid in conformity to the requirements of the
Constitution. It is, therefore, necessary to ascertain to which of the
categories named in the eighth section of the first article it belongs.
"What are direct taxes was elaborately argued and considered by this court
in Hylton v. United States, decided in the year 1796.One of the members of the
court, Justice Wilson, had been a distinguished member of the convention
[**708] which framed the Constitution. It was unanimously held by
the four justices who heard the argument that a tax upon carriages kept by the
owner for his own use was not a direct tax. Justice Chase said: 'I am inclined
to think, but of this I do not give a judicial opinion, that the direct taxes
contemplated by the Constitution are only two, to [***361] wit, a
capitation or poll tax simply, without regard to property, profession, or any
other circumstances, and a tax on land.' Paterson, Justice, followed in the
same line of remark. He said: 'I never entertained a doubt that the principal
-- I will not say [*629] the only -- object the framers of the
Constitution contemplated as falling within the rule of apportionment was a
capitation tax or a tax on land. . . . The Constitution declares that a
capitation tax is a direct tax; and both in theory and practice a tax on land
is deemed to be a direct tax. In this way the terms "direct taxes"
and "capitation and other direct taxes" are satisfied.'
"The views expressed in this case are adopted by Chancellor Kent and
Justice Story, in their examination of the subject. Duties are defined by
Tomlin to be things due and recoverable by law. The term, in its widest
signification, is hardly less comprehensive than 'taxes.' It is applied, in its
most restricted meaning, to customs; and in that sense is nearly the synonym of
'imposts.'
"Impost is a duty on imported goods and merchandise. In a larger sense, it
is any tax or imposition. Cowell says it is distinguished from custom, 'because
[***362] custom is rather the profit which the prince makes on
goods shipped out.' Mr. Madison considered the terms 'duties' and imposts' in
these clauses as synonymous. Judge Tucker thought 'they were probably intended
to comprehend every species of tax or contribution not included under the
ordinary terms, "taxes and excises."'
"Excise is defined to be an inland imposition, sometimes upon the
consumption of the commodity, and sometimes upon the retail sale; sometimes
upon the manufacturer, and sometimes upon the vendor.
"The taxing power is given in the most comprehensive terms. The only
limitations imposed are: That direct taxes, including the capitation tax, shall
be apportioned; that duties, imposts, and excises shall be uniform; and that no
duties shall be imposed upon articles exported from any State. With these
exceptions, the exercise of the power is, in all respects, unfettered.
"If a tax upon carriages, kept for his own use by the owner, is not a
direct tax, we can see no ground upon which a tax upon the business on an
insurance company can be held to belong to that class of revenue charges.
"It has been held that Congress may require direct taxes to [*630]
be laid [***363] and collected in the Territories as well as in the
States.
"The consequences which would follow the apportionment of the tax in
question among the States and Territories of the Union, in the manner
prescribed by the Constitution, must not be overlooked. They are very obvious.
Where such corporations are numerous and rich, it might be light; where none
exist, it could not be collected; where they are few and poor, it would fall
upon them with such weight as to involve annihilation. It cannot be supposed
that the framers of the Constitution intended that any tax should be
apportioned, the collection of which on that principle would be attended with
such results. The consequences are fatal to the proposition.
"To the question under consideration it must be answered, that the tax to
which it relates is not a direct tax, but a duty or excise; that it was
obligatory on the plaintiff to pay it.
"The other questions certified up are deemed to be sufficiently answered
by the answers given to the first and sixth questions."
This opinion, it seems to me, closes the door to discussion in regard to the
meaning of the word "direct" in the Constitution, and renders
unnecessary and resort [***364] to the conflicting opinions of the
framers, or to the theories of the economists. It adopts that construction of
the word which confines it to capitation taxes and a tax on land, and
necessarily rejects the contention that that word was to be construed in
accordance with the economic theory of shifting a tax from the shoulders of the
person upon whom it was immediately levied to those of some other person. This
decision, moreover, is of great importance because it is an authoritative
reaffirmance of the Hylton case, and an approval of the suggestions there made
by the justices, and constitutes another sanction given by this court to the
interpretation of the Constitution adopted by the legislative, executive, and
judicial departments of the government, and thereafter continuously acted upon.
Not long thereafter, in Veazie Bank v. Fenno, 8 Wall. 533, 541, 546, the
question of the application of the word "direct" was again submitted
to this court. The issue there was whether a tax on the circulation of state
banks was "direct" within [*631] the meaning of the
Constitution. It was ably argued by the most distinguished counsel; Reverdy
Johnson and Caleb Cushing representing [***365] the bank, and
Attorney General Hoar the United States. The brief of Mr. Cushing again
presented nearly every point now urged upon our consideration. It cited
copiously from the opinions of Adam Smith and others. The constitutionality of
the tax was maintained by the government on the ground that the meaning of the
word "direct" in the Constitution, as interpreted by the Hylton case,
as enforced by the continuous legislative construction, and as sanctioned by
the consensus of opinion already referred to, was finally settled. Those who
assailed the tax there urged, as is done here, that the Hylton case was not
conclusive, because the only question decided was the particular matter
[**709] at issue, and insisted that the suggestions of the judges
were mere dicta, and not to be followed. They said that Hylton v. United States
adjudged one point alone, which was that a tax on a carriage was not a direct
tax, and that from the utterances of the judges in the case it was obvious that
the general question of what was a direct tax was but crudely considered. Thus
the argument there presented to this court the very view of the Hylton case
which has been reiterated in the [***366] argument here, and which
is sustained now. What did this court say then, speaking through Chief Justice
Chase, as to these arguments? I take very fully from its opinion:
"Much diversity of opinion has always prevailed upon the question, what
are direct taxes? Attempts to answer it by reference to the definitions of
political economists have been frequently made, but without satisfactory
results. The enumeration of the different kinds of taxes which Congress was
authorized to impose was probably made with very little reference to their
speculations. The great work of Adam Smith, the first comprehensive treatise on
political economy in the English language, had then been recently published;
but in this work, though there are passages which refer to the characteristic
difference between direct and indirect taxation, there is nothing which affords
any valuable light on the use of the words 'direct taxes' in the Constitution.
[*632] "We are obliged, therefore, to resort to historical
evidence, and to seek the meaning of the words in the use and in the opinion of
those whose relations to the government, and means of knowledge, warranted them
in speaking with authority.
"And [***367] considered in this light, the meaning and
application of the rule, as to direct taxes, appears to us quite clear.
"It is, as we think, distinctly shown in every act of Congress on the
subject.
"In each of these acts, a gross sum was laid upon the United States, and
the total amount was apportioned to the several States according to their
respective numbers of inhabitants, as ascertained by the last preceding census.
Having been apportioned, provision was made for the imposition of the tax upon
the subjects specified in the act, fixing its total sum.
"In 1798, when the first direct tax was imposed, the total amount was
fixed at two millions of dollars; in 1813, the amount of the second direct tax
was fixed at three millions; in 1815, the amount of the third at six millions, and
it made an annual tax; in 1816, the provision making the tax annual was
repealed by the repeal of the first section of the act of 1815, and the total
amount was fixed for that year at three millions of dollars.No other direct tax
was imposed until 1861, when a direct tax of twenty millions of dollars was
laid and made annual; but the provision making it annual was suspended, and no
tax, except that first [***368] laid, was ever apportioned. In each
instance, the total sum was apportioned among the States, by the constitutional
rule, and was assessed at prescribed rates on the subjects of the tax. These
subjects, in 1798, 1813, 1815, 1816, were lands, improvements, dwelling houses,
and slaves, and in 1861 lands, imprevements, and dwelling houses only. Under
the act of 1798 slaves were assessed at fifth cents on each; under the other
acts, according to valuation by assessors.
"This review shows that personal property, contracts, occupations, and the
like have never been regarded by Congress as proper subjects of direct tax. It
has been supposed that slaves must be considered as an exception to this
observation. But the exception is rather apparent than real. As persons, slaves
[*633] were proper subjects of a capitation tax, which is described
in the Constitution as a direct tax; as property they were, by the laws of
some, if not most, of the States classed as real property, descendible to
heirs. Under the first view they would be subject to the tax of 1798, as a
capitation tax; under the latter, they would be subject to the taxation of the
other years as realty. That the latter [***369] view was that taken
by the framers of the acts, after 1798, becomes highly probable, when it is
considered that, in the States where slaves were held, much of the value which
would otherwise have attached to land passed into the slaves. If, indeed, the
land only had been valued without the slaves, the land would have been subject
to much heavier proportional imposition in those States than in States where
there were no slaves; for the proportion of tax imposed on each State was
determined by population, without reference to the subjects on which it was to
be assessed.
"The fact, then, that slaves were valued, under the acts referred to, far
from showing, as some have supposed, that Congress regarded personal property
as a proper object of direct taxation under the Constitution, shows only that
Congress, after 1798, regarded slaves, for the purposes of taxation, as realty.
"It may be rightly affirmed, therefore, that in the practical construction
of the Constitution by Congress direct taxes have been limited to taxes on land
and appurtenances and taxes on polls or capitation taxes.
"And this construstion is entitled to great consideration, expecially in
the absence of anything [***370] adverse to it in the discussions
of the convention which framed and of the conventions which ratified the
Constitution. . . .
"This view received the sanction of this court two years before the
enactment of the first law imposing direct taxes eo nomine."
The court then reviews the Hylton case, repudiates the attack made upon it,
reaffirms the construction placed on it by the legislative, executive, and
judicial departments, and [**710] expressly adheres to the ruling
in the insurance company case, to which I have referred. Summing up, it said:
[*634] "It follows necessarily that the power to tax without
apportionment extends to all other objects. Taxes on other objects are included
under the heads of taxes not direct, duties, imposts, and excises, and must be
laid and collected by the rule of uniformity. The tax under consideration is a
tax on bank circulation, and may very well be classed under the head of duties.
Certainly it is not, in the sense of the Constitution, a direct tax. It may be
said to come within the same category of taxation as the tax on incomes of
insurance companies, which this court, at the last term, in the case of Pacific
Insurance Company [***371] v. Soule, held not to be a direct
tax."
This case was, so far as the question of direct taxation is concerned, decided
by an undivided court; for, although Mr. Justice Nelson dissented from the
opinion, it was not on the ground that the tax was a direct tax, but on another
question.
Some years after this decision the matter again came here for adjudication, in
the case of Scholey v. Rew, 23 Wall. 331, 346. The issue there involved was the
validity of a tax placed by a United States statute on the right to take real
estate by inheritance. The collection of the tax was resisted on the ground
that it was direct. The brief expressly urged this contention, and said the tax
in question was a tax on land, if ever there was one. It discussed the Hylton
case, referred to the language used by the various judges, and sought to place
upon it the construction which we are now urged to give it, and which has been
so often rejected by this court.
This court again by its unanimous judgment answered all these contentions. I
quote its language:
"Support to the first objection is attempted to be drawn from that clause
of the Constitution which provides that direct taxes shall [***372]
be apportioned among the several States which may be included within the Union,
according to their respective numbers; and also from the clause which provides
that no capitation or other direct tax shall be laid unless in proportion to
the census or amended enumeration; but it is clear that the tax or duty levied
by the act under consideration is not a direct tax within the meaning of either
of those [*635] provisions. Instead of that it is plainly an excise
tax or duty, authorized by section eight of article one, which vests the power
in Congress to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and excises, to pay the
debts, and provide for the common defence and general welfare. . . .
"Indirect taxes, such as duties of impost and excises and every other
description of the same, must be uniform, and direct taxes must be laid in
proportion to the census or enumeration as remodelled in the Fourteenth
Amendment. Taxes on lands, houses, and other permanent real estate have always
been deemed to be direct taxes, and capitation taxes, by the express words of
the Constitution, are within the same category, but it never has been decided
that any other legal exactions for the support of [***373] the
Federal government fall within the condition that unless laid in proportion to
numbers the assessment is invalid.
"Whether direct taxes, in the sense of the Constitution, comprehend any
other tax than a capitation tax and a tax on land is a question not absolutely
decided, nor is it necessary to determine it in the present case, as it is
expressly decided that the term does not include the tax on income which cannot
be distinguished in principle from a succession tax such as the one involved in
the present controversy."
What language could more clearly and forcibly reaffirm the previous rulings of
the court upon this subject? What stronger endorsement could be given to the
construction of the Constitution, which had been given in the Hylton case, and
which had been adopted and adhered to by all branches of the government, almost
from the hour of its establishment? It is worthy of note that the court here
treated the decision in the Hylton case as conveying the view that the only
direct taxes were "taxes on land and appurtenance." In so doing it
necessarily again adopted the suggestion of the justices there made, thus
making them the adjudged conclusions of this court. It [***374] is
too late now to destroy the force of the opinions in that case by qualifying
them as mere dicta when they have again and again been expressly approved by
this court.
If there were left a doubt as to what this established construction
[*636] is, it seems to be entirely removed by the case of Springer
v. United States, 102 U.S. 586, 602. Springer was assessed for an income tax on
his professional earnings and on the interest on United States bonds. He
declined to pay. His real estate was sold in consequence. The suit involved the
validity of the tax, as a basis for the sale. Again every question now
presented was urged upon this court.The brief of the plaintiff in error,
Springer, made the most copious references to the economic writers, Continental
and English. It cited the opinions of the framers of the Constitution. It
contained extracts from the journals of the convention, and marshalled the
authorities in extensive and impressive array. It reiterated the argument
against the validity of an income tax which included rentals. It is also
asserted that the Hylton case was not authority, because the expressions of the
judges, in regard to anything except the carriage [***375] tax,
were mere dicta.
The court adhered to the ruling announced in the previous cases and held that
the tax was not direct within the meaning of the Constitution. It reexamined
and answered everything advanced here, and said, in summing up the case:
"Our conclusions are that direct taxes, within the meaning of the
Constitution, are only capitation taxes, as expressed in that instrument,
[**711] and taxes on real estate; and that the tax of which the
plaintiff in error complained is within the category of an excise or
duty."
The facts, then, are briefly these: At the very birth of the government a
contention arose as to the meaning of the word "direct." The
controversy was determined by the legislative and executive departments of the
government. Their action came to this court for review, and it was approved.
Every judge of this court who expressed an opinion, made use of language which
clearly showed that he thought the word "direct" in the Constitution
applied only to capitation taxes and taxes directly on land. Thereafter the
construction thus given was accepted everywhere as definitive. The matter came again
and again to this court, and in every case the original [***376]
ruling was adhered to. The suggestions made in the Hylton case were adopted
here, and, [*637] in the last case here decided, reviewing all the
others, this court ssaid that direct taxes within the meaning of the
Constitution were only taxes on land and capitation taxes. And now, after a
hundred years, after long-continued action by other departments of the
government, and after repeated adjudications of this court, this interpretation
is overthrown, and the Congress is declared not to have a power of taxation
which may at some time, as it has in the past, prove necessary to the very
existence of the government. By what process of reasoning is this to be done?
By resort to theories, in order to construe the word "direct" in its
economic sense, instead of in accordance with its meaning in the Constitution,
when the very result of the history which I have thus briefly recounted is to
show that the economic construction of the word was repudiated by the framers
themselves, and has been time and time again rejected by this court; by a
resort to the language of the framers and a review of their opinions, although
the facts plainly show that they themselves settled the [***377] question
which the court now virtually unsettles. In view of all that has taken place
and of the many decisions of this court, the matter at issue here ought to be
regarded as closed forever.
The injustice and harm which must always result from overthrowing a long and
settled practice sanctioned by the decisions of this court, could not be better
illustrated than by the example which this case affords. Under the income tax
laws which prevailed in the past for many years, and which covered every
conceivable source of income, rentals from real estate, and everything else,
vast sums were collected from the people of the United States. The decision
here rendered announces that those sums were wrongfully taken, and thereby, it
seems to me, creates a claim in equity and good conscience against the
government for an enormous amount of money. Thus, from the change of view by
this court, it happens that an act of Congress, passed for the purpose of
raising revenue, in strict conformity with the practice of the government from the
earliest time and in accordance with the oft-repeated decisions of this court,
furnishes the [*638] occasion for creating a claim against the
government [***378] for hundreds of millions of dollars; I say,
creating a claim, because if the government be in good conscience bound to
refund that which has been taken from the citizen in violation of the
Constitution, although the technical right may have disappeared by lapse of
time, or because the decisions of this court have misled the citizen to his grievous
injury, the equity endures, and will present itself to the conscience of the
government. This consequence shows how necessary it is that the court should
not overthrow its past decisions. A distinguished writer aptly points out the
wrong which must result to society from a shifting judicial interpretation. He
says:
"If rules and maxims of law were to ebb and flow with the taste of the
judge, or to assume that shape which in his fancy best becomes the times; if
the decisions of one case were not to be ruled by, or depend at all upon former
determinations in other cases of a like nature, I should be glad to know what
person would venture to purchase an estate without first having the judgment of
a court of justice respecting the identical title which he means to purchase?
No reliance could be had upon precedents; former resolutions upon
[***379] titles of the same kind could afford him no assurance at
all. Nay, even a decision of a court of justice upon the very identical title
would be nothing more than a precarious temporary security; the principle upon
which it was founded might, in the course of a few years become antiquated; the
same title might be again drawn into dispute; the taste and fashion of the
times might be improved, and on that ground a future judge might hold himself
at liberty (if not consider it his duty) to pay as little regard to the maxims
and decisions of his predecessor as that predecessor did to the maxims and
decisions of those who went before him." Fearne on Contingent Remainders,
London ed. 1801, p. 264.
The disastrous consequences to flow from disregarding settled decisions thus
cogently described must evidently become greatly magnified in a case like the
present, when the opinion of the court affects fundamental principles of the
government by denying an essential power of taxation [*639] long
conceded to exist and often exerted by Congress. If it was necessary that the
previous decisions of this court should be repudiated, the power to amend the
Constitution existed and should have been [***380] availed of.
Since the Hylton case was decided the Constitution has been repeatedly amended.
The construction which confined the word "direct" to capitation and
land taxes was not changed by these amendments, and it should not now be
reversed by what seems to me to be a judicial amendment of the Constitution.
The finding of the court in this case, that the inclusion of rentals from real
estate in an income tax makes it direct to that extent is, in my judgment,
conclusively denied by the [**712] authorities, to which I have
referred, and which establish the validity of an income tax in itself. Hence, I
submit, the decision necessarily reverses the settled rule which it seemingly
adopts in part. Can there be serious doubt that the question of the validity of
an income tax, in which the rentals of real estate are included, is covered by
the decisions which say that an income tax is generically indirect, and that
therefore it is valid without apportionment? I mean, of course, could there be
any such doubt were it not for the present opinion of the court? Before
undertaking to answer this question I deem it necessary to consider some
arguments advanced or suggestions made. [***381]
1st. The opinions of Turgot and Smith and other economists are cited, and it is
said their views were known to the framers of the Constitution; and we are then
referred to the opinions of the framers themselves. The object of the
collocation of these two sources of authority is to show that there was a concurrence
between them as to the meaning of the word "direct." But, in order to
reach this conclusion, we are compelled to overlook the fact that this court
has always held, as appears from the preceding cases, that the opinions of the
economists threw little or no light on the interpretation of the word
"direct" as found in the Constitution. And the whole effect of the
decisions of this court is to establish the proposition that the word has a
different significance in the Constitution from that which Smith and Turgot
have given to it when used in a general economic sense. Indeed, it seems to me
[*640] that the conclusion deduced from this line of thought itself
demonstrates its own unsoundness. What is that conclusion? That the framers
well understood the meaning of "direct."
Now, it seems evident that the framers, who well understood the meaning of this
word, have [***382] themselves declared in the most positive way
that it shall not be here construed in the sense of Smith and Turgot. The
Congress which passed the carriage-tax act was composed largely of men who had
participated in framing the Constitution. That act was approved by Washington,
who had presided over the deliberations of the convention. Certainly Washington
himself, and the majority of the framers, if they well understood the sense in
which the word "direct" was used, would have declined to adopt and
approve a taxing act, which clearly violated the provisions of the
Constitution, if the word "direct" as therein used, had the meaning
which must be attached to it, if read by the light of the theories of Turgot
and Adam Smith. As has already been noted, all the judges who expressed
opinions in the Hylton case suggested that "direct," in the
constitutional sense, referred only to taxes on land and capitation taxes.
Could they have possibly made this suggestion if the word had been used as
Smith and Turgot used it? It is immaterial whether the suggestions of the
judges were dicta or not. They could not certainly have made this intimation, if
they understood the meaning of [***383] the word
"direct," as being that which it must have imported if construed
according to the writers mentioned. Take the language of Mr. Justice Paterson:
"I never entertained a doubt that the principal, I will not say the only,
objects that the framers of the Constitution contemplated as falling within the
rule of apportionment were a capitation tax and a tax on land." He had
borne a conspicuous part in the convention. Can we say that he understood the
meaning of the framers, and yet after the lapse of a hundred years, fritter
away that language, uttered by him from this bench in the first great case in
which this court was called upon to interpret the meaning of the word
"direct?" It cannot be said that his language was used carelessly or
without a knowledge of its great import. The debate upon the passage
[*641] of the carriage-tax act had manifested divergence of opinion
as to the meaning of the word "direct." The magnitude of the issue is
shown by all contemporaneous authority to have been deeply felt and its
far-reaching consequence was appreciated. Those controversies came here for
settlement and were then determined with a full knowledge of the importance of
the issues. [***384] They should not be now reopened.
The argument, then, it seems to me, reduces itself to this: That the framers
well knew the meaning of the word "direct;" that so well
understanding it they practically interpreted it in such a way as to plainly
indicate that it had a sense contrary to that now given to it in the view
adopted by the court. Although they thus comprehended the meaning of the word
and interpreted it at an early day, their interpretation is now to be
overthrown by resorting to the economists whose construction was repudiated by
them. It is thus demonstrable that the conclusion deduced from the premise that
the framers well understood the meaning of the word "direct,"
involves a fallacy. In other words, that it draws a faulty conclusion, even if
the predicate upon which the conclusion is rested by fully admitted. But I do
not admit the premise. The views of the framers cited in the argument
conclusively show that they did not well understand, but were in great doubt as
to the meaning of the word "direct." The use of the word was the
result of a compromise. It was accepted as the solution of a difficulty which
threatened to frustrate the hopes of those who looked [***385] upon
the formation of a new government as absolutely necessary to escape the
condition of weakness which the Articles of Confederation had shown. Those who
accepted the compromise viewed the word in different lights and expected
different results to flow from its adoption. This was the natural result of the
struggle which was terminated by the adoption of the provision as to
representation [**713] and direct taxes. That warfare of opinion
had been engendered by the existence of slavery in some of the States, and was
the consequence of the conflict of interest thus brought about. In reaching a
settlement, the minds of those who acted on it were naturally concerned in the
main with the cause of the [*642] contention and not with the other
things, which had been previously settled by the convention. Thus, whilst there
was in all probability clearness of vision as to the meaning of the word
"direct," in relation to its bearing on slave property, there was
inattention in regard to other things, and there were, therefore, diverse
opinions as to its proper signification. That such was the case in regard to
many other clauses of the Constitution has been shown to be the case
[***386] by those great controversies of the past which have been
peacefully settled by the adjudications of this court. Whilst this difference
undoubtedly existed, as to the effect to be given the word "direct,"
the consensus of the majority of the framers as to its meaning was shown by the
passage of the carriage-tax act. That consensus found adequate expression in
the opinions of the justices in the Hylton case, and in the decree of this
court there rendered. The passage of that act, those opinions and that decree,
settled the proposition that the word applied only to capitation taxes and
taxes on land.
Nor does the fact that there was difference in the minds of the framers as to
the meaning of the word "direct" weaken the binding force of the
interpretation placed upon that word from the beginning. For, if such
difference existed, it is certainly sound to hold that a contemporaneous
solution of a doubtful question, which has been often confirmed by this court,
should not now be reversed. The framers of the Constitution, the members of the
earliest Congress, the illustrious man first called to the office of Chief
Executive, the jurists who first sat in this court, two of whom had
[***387] borne a great part in the labors of the convention, all of
whom dealt with this doubtful question, surely occupied a higher vantage ground
for its correct solution than do those of our day. Here then is the dilemma: if
the framers understood the meaning of the word "direct" in the
Constitution, the practical effect which they gave to it should remain
undisturbed; if they were in doubt as to the meaning, the interpretation long
since authoritatively affixed to it should be upheld.
2d. Nor do I think any light is thrown upon the question of whether the tax
here under consideration is direct or indirect, [*643] by referring
to the principle of "taxation without representation," and the great
struggle of our forefathers for its enforcement. It cannot be said that the
Congress which passed this act was not the representative body fixed by the
Constitution. Nor can it be contended that the struggle for the enforcement of
the principle involved the contention that representation should be in exact
proportion to the wealth taxed. If the argument be used in order to draw the
inference that, because in this instance, the indirect tax imposed will operate
differently through [***388] various sections of the country,
therefore that tax should be treated as direct, it seems to me it is unsound.
The right to tax, and not the effects which may follow from its lawful
exercise, is the only judicial question which this court is called upon to
consider. If an indirect tax, which the Constitution has not subjected to the
rule of apportionment, is to be held to be a direct tax, because it will bear
upon aggregations of property in different sections of the country, according
to the extent of such aggregations, then the power is denied to Congress to do
that which the Constitution authorizes, because the exercise of a lawful power
is supposed to work out a result which, in the opinion of the court, was not
contemplated by the fathers. If this be sound, then every question which has
been determined in our past history is now still open for judicial
reconstruction. The justness of tariff legislation has turned upon the
assertion on the one hand, denied on the other, that it operated unequally on
the inhabitants of different sections of the country. Those who opposed such
legislation have always contended that its necessary effect was not only to put
the whole burden upon [***389] one section, but also to directly
enrich certain of our citizens at the expense of the rest, and thus build up
great fortunes to the benefit of the few and the detriment of the many. Whether
this economic contention be true or untrue is not the question. Of course, I
intimate no view on the subject. Will it be said that if to-morrow the
personnel of this court should be changed, it could deny the power to enact
tariff legislation which has been admitted to exist in Congress from the
beginning, upon the ground that such legislation beneficially affects one
section or set of people [*644] to the detriment of others, within
the spirit of the Constitution, and therefore constitutes a direct tax?
3d. Nor, in my judgment, does any force result from the argument that the
framers expected direct taxes to the rarely resorted to, and, as the present
tax was imposed without public necessity, it should be declared void.
It seems to me that this statement begs the whole question, for it assumes that
the act now before us levies a direct tax, whereas the question whether the tax
is direct or not is the very issue involved in this case. If Congress now deems
it advisable to resort to [***390] certain forms of indirect
taxation which have been frequently, though not continuously, availed of in the
past, I cannot see that its so doing affords any reason for converting and
indirect into a direct tax in order to nullify the legislative will. The policy
of any particular method of taxation, or the presence of an exigency which
requires its adoption, is a purely legislative question. [**714] It
seems to me that it violates the elementary distinction between the two
departments of the government to allow an opinion of this court upon the
necessity or expediency of a tax to affect or control our determination of the
existence of the power to impose it.
But I pass from these considerations to approach the question whether the inclusion
of rentals from real estate in an income tax renders such a tax to that extent
"direct" under the Constitution, because it constitutes the
imposition of a direct tax on the land itself.
Does the inclusion of the rentals from real estate in the sum going to make up
the aggregate income from which (in order to arrive at taxable income) is to be
deducted insurance, repairs, losses in business, and four thousand dollars
exemption, make the tax [***391] on income so ascertained a direct
tax on such real estate?
In answering this question we must necessarily accept the interpretation of the
word "direct" authoritatively given by the history of the government
and the decisions of this court just cited. To adopt that interpretation for
the general purposes of an income tax, and then repudiate it because of one of
the elements of which it is composed, would violate every [*645]
elementary rule of construction. So, also, to seemingly accept that
interpretation and then resort to the framers and the economists in order to
limit its application and give it a different significance is equivalent to its
destruction and amounts to repudiating it without directly doing so. Under the
settled interpretation of the word we ascertain whether a tax be direct or not
by considering whether it is a tax on land or a capitation tax. And the tax on
land, to be within the provision for apportionment, must be direct. Therefore
we have two things to take into account: is it a tax on land and is it direct
thereon or so immediately on the land as to be equivalent to a direct levy upon
it? To say that any burden on land, even though indirect, must
[***392] be apportioned is not only to incorporate a new provision
in the Constitution, but is also to obliterate all the decisions to which I
have referred, by construing them as holding that although the Constitution
forbids only a direct tax on land without apportionment, it must be so
interpreted as to bring an indirect tax on land within its inhibition.
It is said that a tax on the rentals is a tax on the land, as if the act here
under consideration imposed an immediate tax on the rentals. This statement, I
submit, is a misconception of the issue. The point involved is whether a tax on
net income, when such income is made up by aggregating all sources of revenue
and deducting repairs, insurance, losses in business, exemptions, etc., becomes
to the extent to which real estate revenues may have entered into the gross
income, a direct tax on the land itself. In other words, does that which
reaches an income, and thereby reaches rentals indirectly, and reaches the land
by a double indirection, amount to direct levy on the land itself? It seems to
me the question when thus accurately stated furnishes its own negative
response. Indeed, I do not see how the issue can be stated [***393]
precisely and logically without making it apparent on its face that the
inclusion of rental from real property in income is nothing more than an
indirect tax upon the land.
It must be borne in mind that we are dealing not with the want of power in
Congress to assess real estate at all; on [*646] the contrary, as I
have shown at the outset, Congress has plenary power to reach real estate both
directly and indirectly. If it taxes real estate directly, the Constitution
commands that such direct imposition shall be apportioned. But because an
excise or other indirect tax, imposed without apportionment, has an indirect
effect upon real estate, no violation of the Constitution is committed, because
the Constitution has left Congress untrammelled by any rule of apportionment as
to indirect taxes -- imposts, duties, and excises. The opinions in the Hylton
case, so often approved and reiterated, the unanimous views of the
text-writers, all show that a tax on land, to be direct, must be an assessment
of the land itself, either by quantity or valuation.Here there is no such
assessment. It is well also to bear in mind, in considering whether the tax is
direct on the land, the fact that [***394] if land yields no rental
it contributes nothing to the income. If it is vacant, the law does not force
the owner to add the rental value to his taxable income. And so it is if he
occupies it himself.
The citation made by counsel from Coke on Littleton, upon which so much stress
is laid, seems to me to have no relevancy. The fact that where one delivers or
agrees to give or transfer land with all the fruits and revenues, it will be
presumed to be a conveyance of the land, in no way supports the proposition
that an indirect tax on the rental of land is a direct burden on the land
itself.
Nor can I see the application of Brown v. Maryland, 12 Wheat. 419; Weston v.
Charleston, 2 Pet. 449; Dobbins v. Erie County Commissioners, 16 Pet. 435; Almy
v. California, 24 How. 169; Cook v. Pennsylvania, 97 U.S. 566; Railroad Co. v.
Jackson, 7 Wall. 262; Philadelphia &c. Steamship Co. v. Pennsylvania, 122
U.S. 326; Leloup v. Mobile, 127 U.S. 640; Postal Telegraph Co. v. Adams, 155
U.S. 688. All these cases involve the question whether, under the Constitution,
if no power existed to tax at all, either directly or indirectly, an indirect
tax would be unconstitutional. These cases would be apposite
[***395] to this if Congress had no power to tax real estate.Were
such the case, it might be that the imposition of an excise by Congress which
reached real estate indirectly would [*647] necessarily violate the
Constitution, because as it had no power in the premises, every attempt to tax
direct or indirectly would be null. Here, on the contrary, it is not denied
that the power to [**715] tax exists in Congress, but the question
is, is the tax direct or indirect in the constitutional sense?
But it is unnecessary to follow the argument further; for, if I understand the
opinions of this court already referred to, they absolutely settle the
proposition that an inclusion of the rentals of real estate in an income tax
does not violate the Constitution. At the risk of repetition, I propose to go
over the cases again for the purpose of demonstrating this. In doing so, let it
be understood at the outset that I do not question the authority of Cohens v.
Virginia, or Carroll v. Lessee of Carroll, or any other of the cases referred
to in argument of counsel. These great opinions hold that an adjudication need
not be extended beyond the principles which it decides. Whilst conceding this,
[***396] it is submitted that, if decided cases do directly,
affirmatively, and necessarily, in principle, adjudicate the very question here
involved, then under the very text of the opinions referred to by the court,
they should conclude this question. In the first case, that of Hylton, is there
any possibility by the subtlest ingenuity to reconcile the decision here
announced with what was there established?
In the second case, Insurance Company v. Soule, the levy was upon the company,
its premiums, its dividends, and net gains from all sources. The case was
certified to this court, and the statement made by the judges in explanation of
the question which they propounded says: "The amount of said premiums,
dividends, and net gains were truly stated in said lists or returns."
Original Record, p. 27.
It will thus be seen that the issue there presented was not whether an income
tax on business gains was valid, but whether an income tax on gains from
business and all other net gains was constitutional. Under this state of facts
the question put to the court was: "Whether the taxes paid by the
plaintiff, and sought to be recovered back, in this action, are not direct
taxes within the meaning [***397] of the Constitution of the United
States."
[*648] This tax covered revenue of every possible nature, and it
therefore appears self-evident that the court could not have upheld the statute
without deciding that the income derived from realty, as well as that derived
from every other source, might be taxed without apportionment. It is obvious
that if the court had considered that any particular subject-matter which the
statute reached was not constitutionally included, it would have been obliged
by every rule of safe judicial conduct to qualify its answer as to this
particular subject.
It is impossible for me to conceive that the court did not embrace in its
ruling the constitutionality of an income tax which included rentals from real
estate, since, without passing upon that question, it could not have decided
the issue presented. And another reason why it is logically impossible that
this question of the validity of the inclusion of the rental of real estate in
an income tax could have been overlooked by the court is found in the fact to
which I could have already adverted, that this was one of the principal points
urged upon its attention, and the argument covered all the [***398]
ground which has been occupied here -- indeed, the very citation from Coke upon
Littleton, now urged as conclusive, was there made also in the brief of
counsel. And although the return of income involved in that case was made
"in block," the very fact that the burden of the argument was that to
include rentals from real estate, in income subject to taxation, made such tax
pro tanto direct, seems to me to indicate that such rentals had entered into
the return made by the corporation.
Again, in the case of Scholey v. Rew, the tax in question was laid directly on
the right to take real estate by inheritance, a right which the United States
had no power to control. The case could not have been decided, in any point of
view, without holding a tax upon that right was not direct, and that,
therefore, it could be levied without apportionment.It is manifest that the
court could not have overlooked the question whether this was a direct tax on
the land or not, because in the argument of counsel it was said, if there was
any tax in the world that was a tax on real estate which was [*649]
direct, that was the one. The court said it was not, and sustained the law. I
repeat [***399] that the tax there was put directly upon the right
to inherit, which Congress had no power to regulate or control. The case was
therefore greatly stronger than that here presented, for Congress has a right
to tax real estate directly with apportionment. That decision cannot be
explained away by saying that the court overlooked the fact that Congress had
no power to tax the devolution of real estate, and treated it as a tax on such
devolution. Will it be said of the distinguished men who then adorned this
bench, that although the argument was pressed upon them that this tax was
levied directly on the real estate, they ignored the elementary principle that
the control of the inheritance of realty is a state and not a Federal function?
But even if the case proceeded upon the theory that the tax was on the
devolution of the real estate and was therefore not direct, is it not absolutely
decisive of this controversy? If to put a burden of taxation on the right to
take real estate by inheritance reaches realty only by indirection, how can it
be said that a tax on the income, the result of all sources of revenue,
including rentals, after deducting losses and expenses, which thus reaches
[***400] the rentals indirectly, and the real estate indirectly
through the rentals, is a direct tax on the real estate itself?
So, it is manifest in the Springer case that the same question was necessarily
decided. It seems obvious that the court intended in that case to decide the
whole question, including [**716] the right to tax rental from real
estate without apportionment. It was elaborately and carefully argued there
that as the law included the rentals of land in the income taxed, and such
inclusion was unconstitutional, this, therefore, destroyed that part of the law
which imposed the tax on the revenues of personal property. Will it be said, in
view of the fact that in this very case four of the judges of this court think
that the inclusion of the rentals from real estate in an income tax renders the
whole law invalid, that the question of the inclusion of rentals was of no
moment there, because the return there did not contain a mention of such rentals?
Were [*650] the great judges who then composed this court so
neglectful that they did not see the importance of a question which is now
considered by some of its members so vital that the result in their opinion is
[***401] to annul the whole law, more especially when that question
was pressed upon the court in argument with all possible vigor and earnestness?
But I think that the opinion in the Springer case clearly shows that the court
did consider this question of importance, that it did intend to pass upon it,
and that it deemed that it had decided all the questions affecting the validity
of an income tax in passing upon the main issue, which included the others as
the greater includes the less.
I can discover no principle upon which these cases can be considered as any
less conclusive of the right to include rentals of land in the concrete result,
income, than they are as to the right to levy a general income tax. Certainly,
the decisions which hold that an income tax as such is not direct, decide on
principle that to include the rentals of real estate in an income tax does not
make it direct. If embracing rentals in income makes a tax on income to that
extent a direct tax on the land, then the same word, in the same sentence of
the Constitution, has two wholly distinct constitutional meanings, and
signifies one thing when applied to an income tax generally, and a different
thing when applied [***402] to the portion of such a tax made up in
part of rentals. That is to say, the word means one thing when applied to the
greater and another when applied to the lesser tax.
My inability to agree with the court in the conclusions which it has just
expressed causes me much regret. Great as is my respect for any view by it
announced, I cannot resist the conviction that its opinion and decree in this
case virtually annuls its previous decisions in regard to the powers of
Congress on the subject of taxation, and is therefore fraught with danger to
the court, to each and every citizen, and to the republic. The conservation and
orderly development of our institutions rests on our acceptance of the results
of the past, and their use as lights to guide our steps in the future. Teach
the lesson that settled principles may be overthrown [*651] at any
time, and confusion and turmoil must ultimately result. In the discharge of its
function of interpreting the Constitution, this court exercises an august
power. It sits removed from the contentions of political parties and the
animosities of factions. It seems to me that the accomplishment of its lofty
mission can only be secured by the [***403] stability of its
teachings and the sanctity which surrounds them. If the permanency of its
conclusions is to depend upon the personal opinions of those who, from time to
time, may make up its membership, it will inevitably become a theatre of
political strife, and its action will be without coherence or consistency.
There is no great principle of our constitutional law, such as the nature and
extent of the commerce power, or the currency power, or other powers of the
Federal government, which has not been ultimately defined by the adjudications
of this court after long and earnest struggle. If we are to go back to the
original sources of our political system, or are to appeal to the writings of
the economists in order to unsettle all these great principles, everything is
lost and nothing saved to the people. The rights of every individual are
guaranteed by the safeguards which have been thrown around them by our adjudications.
If these are to be assailed and overthrown, as is the settled law of income
taxation by this opinion, as I understand it, the rights of property, so far as
the Federal Constitution is concerned, are of little worth. My strong
convictions forbid [***404] that I take part in a conclusion which
seems to me so full of peril to the country.I am unwilling to do so, without
reference to the question of what my personal opinion upon the subject might be
if the question were a new one, and was thus unaffected by the action of the
framers, the history of the government, and the long line of decisions by this
court. The wisdom of our forefathers in adopting a written Constitution has
often been impeached upon the theory that the interpretation of a written instrument
did not afford as complete protection to liberty as would be enjoyed under a
Constitution made up of the traditions of a free people. Writing, it has been
said, does not insure greater stability than tradition does, while it
[*652] destroys flexibility. The answer has always been that by the
foresight of the fathers the construction of our written Constitution was
ultimately confided to this body, which, from the nature of its judicial
structure, could always be relied upon to act with perfect freedom from the
influence of faction and to preserve the benefits of consistent interpretation.
The fundamental conception of a judicial body is that of one hedged about by
precedents [***405] which are binding on the court without regard
to the personality of its members. Break down this belief in judicial
continuity, and let it be felt that on great constitutional questions this
court is to depart from the settled conclusions of its predecessors, and to
determine them all according to the mere opinion of those who
[**717] temporarily fill its bench, and our Constitution will, in
my judgment, be bereft of value and become a most dangerous instrument to the
rights and liberties of the people.
In regard to the right to include in an income tax the interest upon the bonds
of municipal corporations, I think the decisions of this court, holding that
the Federal government is without power to tax the agencies of the state
government, embrace such bonds, and that this settled line of authority is
conclusive upon my judgment here. It determines the question that where there
is no power to tax for any purpose whatever, no direct or indirect tax can be
imposed. The authorities cited in the opinion are decisive of this question.
They are relevant to one case and not to the other, because, in the one case,
there is full power in the Federal government to tax, the only controversy
[***406] being whether the tax imposed is direct or indirect; while
in the other there is no power whatever in the Federal government, and,
therefore, the levy, whether direct or indirect, is beyond the taxing power.
Mr. Justice Harlan authorizes me to say that he concurs in the views herein
expressed.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN further dissenting.
I concur so entirely in the general views expressed by Mr. Justice White in
reference to the questions disposed of by the [*653] opinion and
judgment of the majority, that I will do no more than indicate, without
argument, the conclusions reached by me after much consideration. Those conclusions
are:
1. Giving due effect to the statutory provision that "no suit for the
purpose of restraining the assessment or collection of any tax shall be
maintained in any court," Rev. Stat. § 3224, the decree below dismissing
the bill should be affirmed.As the Farmers' Loan and Trust Company could not
itself maintain a suit to restrain either the assessment or collection of the
tax imposed by the act of Congress, the maintenance of a suit by a stockholder
to restrain that corporation and its directors from voluntarily paying such tax
would tend to defeat [***407] the manifest object of the statute,
and be an evasion of its provisions. Congress intended to forbid the issuing of
any process that would interfere in anywise with the prompt collection of the
taxes imposed. The present suits are mere devices to strike down a general
revenue law by decrees, to which neither the government nor any officer of the
United States could be rightfully made parties of record.
2. Upon principle, and under the doctrines announced by this court in numerous
cases, a duty upon the gains, profits, and income derived from the rents of
land is not a "direct" tax on such land within the meaning of the
constitutional provisions requiring capitation or other direct taxes to be
apportioned among the several States, according to their respective numbers
determined in the mode prescribed by that instrument. Such a duty may be
imposed by Congress without apportioning the same among the States according to
population.
3. While property, and the gains, profits, and income derived from property,
belonging to private corporations and individuals, are subjects of taxation for
the purpose of paying the debts and providing for the common defence and the
general welfare [***408] of the United States, the
instrumentalities employed by the States in execution of their powers are not
subjects of taxation by the general government, any more than the
instrumentalities of the United States are the subjects of taxation by the
States; and any tax imposed directly upon interest derived from bonds issued by
a municipal corporation [*654] for public purposes, under the
authority of the State whose instrumentality it is, is a burden upon the
exercise of the powers of that corporation which only the State creating it may
impose. In such a case it is immaterial to inquire whether the tax is, in its
nature or by its operation, a direct or an indirect tax; for the
instrumentalities of the States -- among which, as is well settled, are
municipal corporations, exercising powers and holding property for the benefit
of the public -- are not subjects of national taxation, in any form or for any
purpose, while the property of private corporations and of individuals is
subject to taxation by the general government for national purposes. So it has
been frequently adjudged, and the question is no longer an open one in this
court.
Upon the several questions about which the [***409] members of this
court are equally divided in opinion, I deem it appropriate to withhold any expression
of my views, because the opinion of the Chief Justice is silent in regard to
those questions.